FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 3, No. 5, 5/1/01.
Economic absurdities:
Absurd contentions and absurd futurecasts concerning economic policy have been a deplorable feature of 20th century intellectual and political life.
?The rapid pace of modern developments starkly reveals such economic absurdities - often before the ink is dry on the page proofs.
One of the most interesting phenomena of modern life - and one that it is well to keep in mind as we enter the 21st century - is the many times that the most authoritative and respected intellectuals and professionals have voiced the most absurd contentions about national and world economic policies - and confidently provided us with the most absurd predictions based on those absurdities. Many of these contentions and predictions gained wide acceptance - becoming the "authoritative myths" of their time - among the credulous and the followers of these spokesmen.
?
This is a cautionary tale for those intellectuals and other authoritative individuals who are tempted to eschew analytical objectivity in favor of the advocacy scholarship that supports their ideological or professional commitments. The rapid pace of modern developments starkly reveals such absurdities - often before the ink is dry on the page proofs of publications affected by advocacy scholarship.
?
This list - ranging from Lincoln Steffens and the success of Bolshevist communism on the left at the beginning of the century, to Newt Gingrich and the success of the conservative revolution on the right at the end - is limited to those absurdities clearly disproved by events.
?
There are way too many examples to cover in a short essay, but it is instructive to set forth the FUTURECASTS list of the grossest of these proven absurdities. However, additions to the list are welcome, so readers are invited to send their recommendations.
For the love of socialism: "I have seen the future, and it works!" |
Early in the century, in 1919, we had a classic.
Lincoln Steffens, returning from a visit to Bolshevist Russia,
pronounced: "I have seen the future, and it works!" ? Several accounts of this incident assert that Steffens had composed the statement even before entering Russia. In short, he was wearing ideological blinders. He was determined to see only what he wanted to see. This type of intellectual commitment and suspension of disbelief is a continuing characteristic of advocacy scholarship and a rich source of such absurdities. |
`
"The Soviet economy is proof that, contrary to what many skeptics believed, a socialist command economy can function and even thrive." |
One would have thought it well neigh impossible
for any century to contain another classic like the Steffens
absurdity, but MIT Prof. Paul A. Samuelson actually managed
to top it. What tips the scales in favor of the Samuelson absurdity
is the fact that it was published in his widely used textbook - was apparently accepted without question by a vast number of
the economics professors who used his textbook - and constitutes
the kind of error that can only be made by someone who - regardless
of vast learning of economic theory - really doesn't understand
the dynamics of capitalist markets. ? Samuelson fell prey to the "automation scare." The myth that automation is going to wipe out more jobs than it creates is a derivative of Marxist propaganda mythology. Marxists believe that capitalism is inherently unstable, and will ultimately become so productive that its markets will not be able to absorb all its produce, leading to crisis and unemployment that is chronic and disastrous. ? Incredibly, there are actually many intellectuals who persist in taking some of the Marxist absurdities seriously (as does Samuelson). They have long awaited this crisis, even viewing the Great Depression as proof of the concept's validity. ? In the 1950s, Samuelson and some of his buddies thought they saw the automation handwriting on the wall. In his 1961 textbook - referring to the likelihood that computers would eliminate the office secretary - he expressed alarm that: "One pretty machine does the work of 100 pretty girls." He explained his fears with a quote from an MIT mathematician, Norber Weiner, who asserted in 1950:
It's true that stenographers no longer take dictation
while sitting on your lap (more's the pity), but modern secretaries
have hardly disappeared. Instead, they now perform myriad other
tasks with those computers -- many of which were simply not economically
feasible without computers. (We are also still waiting for the
paperless office.) And, of course, the computer industry itself
has turned out to be one of the greatest job creating industries
worldwide of the 20th century. |
The confidence game:
"My son and I have for some days been purchasing sound common stocks." "The fundamental business of this country . . . is on a sound and prosperous basis." Keynesian economics has made the business cycle "obsolete." "Frankly, if I had any money, I'd buy stocks right now." |
The "Confidence Game" is a
rich source of absurdities. It is played by authoritative figures
whenever some crisis seems imminent. It is frequently continued
with equal vigor after a crisis begins. Of course, the stock
market crash of 1929 brought forth some fine examples. ? Soon after the crash: ? John D. Rockefeller: "My son and I have for some days been purchasing sound common stocks." ? Pres. Herbert Hoover: "The fundamental business of this country - - - is on a sound and prosperous basis." ? Within six months of the crash, the stock market seemed to take perverse pleasure by having its worst sell offs on the day following any such pronouncements by Hoover or by his cabinet chiefs. ? Nevertheless, in the late 1960s, as the dollar began to look vulnerable, Arthur Okun, economic adviser to Pres. Johnson, assured one and all that - because of Keynesian economic policies - the business cycle was "obsolete." Then, in the early 1970s - at the beginning of a 12 year period of economic turmoil and declining common stock values (in inflation adjusted terms) - Pres. Richard Nixon advised: "Frankly, if I had any money, I'd buy stocks right now." ? Obviously, whenever we hear words of calm reassurance from such authoritative voices, it's time to make sure that your economic storm cellar is well provisioned. |
However, such Confidence Game absurdities are normal and to be expected. To be a classic, an absurdity must come from a source with some colorable pretense of objectivity and knowledge. My favorites are two sources of economic wisdom - Yale economics Prof. Irving Fisher, and the analysts at the New York Times - who began to play the confidence game prior to the 1929 crash and then persisted for some months afterwards.
"an exceptionally brilliant twelve month period" "the most remarkable year"
"Stock prices are not too high and Wall Street will not experience anything in the nature of a crash."
"The market itself will furnish the best clue as to its future course, and will give warnings of its culmination in plenty of time for the average trader to protect himself when necessary."
"the year will be one of the best, from an industrial and commercial standpoint, in the nation's history." |
In July of 1929, with reports of dire conditions
developing all over the world, came this breathless masterpiece
from the N. Y. Times:
And, in August of 1929:
By the beginning of September, 1929, a sense of unease, accompanied by extreme market volatility, had been initiated when "statistician" Roger Babson provided a remarkably prescient prediction of the mechanism and extent of the coming collapse. However, the prominent Prof. Irving Fisher was quickly brought in to calm the multitudes:
Again, on October 22, 1929 - as the market gyrated
wildly at levels below its September high - Fisher provided calming
assurances that market prices were not too high, and indeed had
not yet reached their true value.
And, again, in mid September, 1929, from the N. Y. Times:
|
"A wild and abnormal chapter in financial history has been definitely closed and a new chapter of financial sanity opened." |
The New York Times began the second phase
of the Confidence Game, on November 1, after the Crash, providing
assurances to one and all. Noting the massive fall in margin
loans, and continuing to ignore the worsening storm in the world outside the
U.S., it stated confidently:
In the months after the crash, the Confidence Game
continued, with participants from business, labor, government,
and the financial and academic community chipping in. In mid
February, 1930, Prof. Fisher called the stock break "unreasoning,"
and firmly predicted that business would soon recover. The market
crash would have only a temporary effect. The N. Y. Times
reported that brokers were "mystified" by continued
waves of heavy selling, and of course provided the ever popular
assurance that the market was now at "bargain" levels.
No economic depression was foreseen, interest rates were plummeting
and money was plentiful, and everyone was congratulating themselves
that business that spring remained so strong. |
The Confidence Game didn't just fool some ordinary investors. Over 50% of industrial companies listed on the New York Stock Exchange bought in their own shares at the "low" prices available in 1930. However, among those who rejected the Confidence Game, and foresaw a long depression (lasting from two - to - five years from April, 1931), was an economist, John Maynard Keynes. |
A preternatural trust in government economic management: |
The competition between capitalism
and socialism was a feature of intellectual discourse and
the ideological foundation of the Cold War. Capitalism is not
an utopian system and does not promise utopian results. The economic
freedom of capitalism provides a rich, creative, but messy brew
which many intellectuals find disquieting. In their desire to
find a better, kinder, more orderly way, they inevitably fall
prey to concepts that would substitute government economic management
for the management mechanisms of profit driven market directed capitalism. ? |
Events perversely refuse to conform to ideological expectations.
|
To sustain their ideology, they must turn a blind
eye to the obvious inherent limitations of government management.
This they often do with commendable wit and style, influencing
the credulous, but ultimately suffering from the perverse refusal
of events to conform to their ideological expectations. |
Convergence of socialism and capitalism:
It is illogical - part of a peculiar technocratic secular religion - that CEOs and other corporate officials routinely work six day, 60 hour weeks for the benefit of such powerless, useless shareholders.
The role of "shareholder value" is determinedly ignored.
|
The most absurd of Galbraith's many absurdities - a true
classic - is his prediction concerning
"convergence." What separates it from his other absurdities,
and makes it a classic, is the favorable response that it received
amongst a substantial number of supposedly intelligent and learned
economists and other intellectuals. The prediction was, of course,
patently irrational and could only be seriously entertained by
those who didn't really understand what makes capitalism work. ? Galbraith strongly asserted that socialist and capitalist systems were inevitably converging on a centralized command economy model with respect to their larger and most important economic entities. In 1972, he asserted that shareholders and even the top management of the larger and most important capitalist corporations had lost effective control.
With this view, Galbraith advocated that government
"pay off such functionless stockholders in bonds and have
the dividends and capital gains accrue to the public." |
Delusions of grandeur: |
But that is not all. Galbraith had delusions
of grandeur for himself and his fellow academic intellectuals. ? |
The academic and scientific community would unite and eventually wrest substantial economic control from shareholders in the capitalist nations, and from the government apparatchiks in the Soviet Union. |
The propaganda
myth created by Karl Marx is viewed quite favorably by Galbraith. He treated many of these quintessential absurdities as profound economic
truths. His strongest criticism of Marx is that Communism is not
the end of the line of economic evolution. ? Since the technocracy is dependent on educators and scientists for the training of additional technocrats and the provision of scientific advances, Galbraith expected the academic and scientific community to unite and eventually wrest substantial economic control from shareholders in the capitalist nations, and from the government apparatchiks in the Soviet Union. This development would thus provide a "convergence" on a command economy model in the further development of the two economic systems. ? The hand that grants the academic degree will rule the economic world! ? |
Of course, intellectual groups would continue - like other interest groups - to occasionally influence legislation of commercial significance. However, Galbraith's expectation that intellectual interests will displace shareholder interests as the controlling factor in corporate policy is yet another of his unfulfilled expectations - and a classic absurdity. |
Government |
In the 1980s, MIT economics Prof.
Lester C. Thurow, in a string of authoritative
books, was driven by his ideological passions towards support for government
"industrial policy." He expressed very favorable views
of those industries nationalized or otherwise controlled by foreign
governments that could thereby be directed to fulfill various
societal needs. ? |
Thurow's obvious intent was to achieve by industrial policy
many of the same results achieved by nationalization. The privatization movement
must have come as a shock to Thurow. Here's a breathless example
of his reasoning:
Clearly, if Thurow
were a general, his tactics would be as disastrous as his proposed
economic policies. |
Adam Smith was wrong. Mercantilist policies are best.
|
And what type of foresight and wisdom does Thurow
believe such "industrial policy" would provide us? ? Industrial policy would:
|
The Rube Goldberg of social engineers: |
It's when Thurow starts to explain his system for government "industrial planning" that we get a good idea why we must never allow Government - with or without the assistance of intellectuals like Thurow - to direct economic development. He advocates a Rube Goldberg reorganization of U.S. business organizations and commercial arrangements. |
Government banks to allocate credit: Government Restructuring Board to influence corporate restructuring decisions: Industrial Policy Board to establish industrial policy: |
Proposal: There should be Government banks
to allocate credit. (Government should pick the winners and losers
among competitive business entities, just like in Asia.) ? Proposal: There should be a Government Restructuring Board, which would "negotiate" with firms as to which facilities they would be permitted to close down, and which should be restructured. (The application of political imperatives, bureaucratic imperatives, and a due process decision-making process would make our economy even less flexible than that of India.) ? Proposal: There should be an Industrial Policy Board to direct broad economic policies. (And Lester Thurow or similar intellectuals should be placed in control, of course.) |
The Conservative Revolution: The ultimate outcome of conservative victories is hardly evidence of a conservative turn in government policy. |
House Speaker Newt Gingrich was the most prominent of the purveyors of the
late 20th century myth of the Conservative (or "Reagan") Revolution. ? That conservative forces had many policy and electoral victories in the last 20 years of the 20th century against the previously predominant liberal Democratic majority is not in question. Nor is there any question concerning the reason for those victories. However, the ultimate outcome of those victories is hardly evidence of a conservative turn in government policy. ? |
Conservative opposition has actually served to strengthen liberalism.
Conservative successes in the 1980s have provided the basis for the great prosperity that today funds an ever greater array of liberal government programs. |
Twentieth
century liberalism - even if by some other name - will continue to drive
American political policies for the foreseeable future. Now that
"liberal" is a dirty word - and politicians of both major political
parties - like Presidents Clinton and Bush - carefully occupy
centrist territory - it is time to acknowledge the tremendous victory of 20th
century liberal ideals during the past 100 years. Assertions that "the era
of big government is over" are certainly premature - and constitute
nothing more than just another Clinton prevarication. The proclamation by
Gingrich and other conservatives of a
new conservative majority is an obviously absurd myth. |
The conservative role:
Conservative opposition to 20th century liberal expansion of the domestic role of the Federal government has had several primary impacts.
?First, it has forced liberal forces to generate wide support for their measures - to make the political compromises essential for that support - and to sometimes more carefully delineate the objectives and boundaries of their initiatives. When conservative opposition has been weak, liberal programs have frequently been overdrawn or obviously impractical - leading to embarrassing failures and conservative political advantage.
?Second, it has facilitated reduction or elimination of those liberal initiatives that work so poorly that they lose public support. Examples include:
- The "energy crisis war" of the 1970s was eliminated so that market mechanisms could efficiently allocate energy resources and assure ample cheap energy supplies for the rest of the 20th century. The current cyclical surge in energy prices will similarly be easily handled by market mechanisms, unless inflationary monetary policies or administered prices are imposed on the economy.
- The federal welfare entitlement has been eliminated, and federal welfare programs have been scaled back and placed within state jurisdiction. This has permitted states to pursue a variety of flexible alternatives that have been far more successful than the centralized federal effort.
- Socialist and "industrial policy" initiatives have been checked and substantially scaled back by the destruction of their intellectual legitimacy. The disasters of European socialism have been avoided, and the burdens of "industrial policy" have been substantially limited. Although far from being eliminated, they have been substantially reduced by the conservative "privatization" and "deregulation" movements. Creative approaches for promoting some competition for markets previously dominated by monopoly utilities have enabled substitution of market disciplines for inefficient regulatory and administrative decision making. The Clinton administration, however, did see a substantial return to heavy-handed economic regulations, and our troubled health care system is probably heading for yet one more disastrous experiment with socialist and administrative decision making approaches.
- Keynesian policies - that were supposed to "obsolete" the business cycle but instead led to the stagflation and other double digit miseries of the 1970s - have been substantially modified. Renewed stress on a strong currency and reasonably balanced budgets provide the basic requirements for current prosperity.
Thirdly, it has concentrated public opposition to judicial decisions that go beyond legitimate "interpretation" of the law - that amount to judicial "legislation" and judicial "amendment" of the Constitution.
?
Judicial activism is thus not totally "undemocratic." Activist decisions that have substantial public approval become established - while decisions that the public comes to dislike - such as those that undermined the effectiveness of the criminal law - are ultimately themselves undermined or reversed. Those that the public simply doesn't care about become points of contest on a continuing litigation battle ground.
?
Conservatives have succeeded in making judicial appointments a political issue. Contested judicial elections have become increasingly common where judicial elections are provided, and judicial nominations are increasingly a political issue nationwide. The courts will thus not be permitted to get too far out ahead of public opinion.
?
The existence, however attenuated, of this political check on judicial activism is vital. As we have seen with the abortion rights controversy - when you remove contentious issues from determination by the ballot, there will inevitably be some who will resort to the bullet.The size and expense of government at the state and local level has exploded in the last decade.
Only the federal government makes its mistakes "from sea to shining sea."
Conservative opposition to liberal programs does not gain traction until failure or gross wastefulness can be demonstrated - or until their cumulative burdens undermine economic prosperity.
Fourth, questions of federalism and tax rates have become the primary political battleground.
?
The "big government" battle has been clearly lost.
- The conservative effort today has been reduced to limiting the growth of the federal government - rather than cutting it back.
- The conservative effort is to reduce taxes - or to at least prevent further tax increases - and to restrain the expansion of government to a rate that is less than that of the economy, so that government programs absorb a declining proportion of our growing gross national product.
- The conservative effort has frequently been reduced to the attempt to have liberal programs administered by state - rather than federal - government whenever practicable.
There thus is at present little political restraint on the growth of state and local governments and their programs. As a result, the size and expense of government at the state and local level has exploded in the last decade, and most of the reduction at the federal level has been as a result of the end of the Cold War. And the Bush administration has proposed federal programs of its own.
?
Thus, as a matter of political tactics, we currently see Democrats championing "fiscal conservatism" - but only as a stratagem for retaining as much tax revenues as possible for future federal programs. Also, we see Republicans championing a variety of government programs - but only as a stratagem to prevent enactment of those programs as "entitlements," and to limit federal participation to programs that the electorate has clearly indicated that it wants.
?
The electorate clearly indicates that it wants a broad range of benefits and services from its governments. This is a democracy, after all, and what the electorate can be convinced that it wants, the electorate will get - whether it likes the results or not. Conservative opposition to liberal programs does not gain traction until failure or gross wastefulness can be demonstrated - or until their cumulative burdens undermine economic prosperity.
?
Today, the results of this process can most dramatically be seen in the nation's largest cities. In both New York City and Los Angeles, successful Republican administrations have cleaned up much of the mess left by liberal predecessors. Now, the city electorates eagerly and overwhelming turn back to liberalism, in the hope of getting more goodies from City Hall.
?State governments collectively are subject to greater disciplinary forces, and are more flexible, than the federal government.
Only the federal government makes its mistakes "from sea to shining sea."
Success in funneling jurisdiction and funds to the states, and in restraining rates of federal growth, are no mere minor matters, however. Liberal social programs - despite the use of "investment" terminology - are economic burdens that can retard or even reverse economic growth.
?
Within broad limits, state and local governments must, at least, compete with each other with respect to their effectiveness and efficiency. They are far more subject to budgetary disciplines. They do not have the power - and thus do not have the temptation - to pay for programs merely by expanding the money supply.
?
Moreover, the states collectively are far more flexible in implementation of programs than the central authority of the federal government. Only the federal government makes its mistakes "from sea to shining sea."
The triumph of 20th century liberalism:
Modern liberalism needs its conservative opposition. Conservative opposition has served to strengthen liberalism by forcing the strengthening of liberal programs, the elimination or rollback of the weakest liberal initiatives, and by restraining the growth of these programs to levels that are not overly burdensome. To repeat - the conservative effort is like a labor of Sisyphus. It's successes since 1980 have provided the bases for the great prosperity that today funds an ever greater array of liberal government programs.
?While the main repository of the liberal cause remains in the Democratic Party, the Republican Party is carving out an increasingly liberal role for itself. Although philosophical differences remain that are far from meaningless, both parties now vie to offer the electorate benefits from the public treasury.
?
The vast resources of a staggeringly prosperous 21st century will be accompanied by a vast expansion of domestic government programs - at the state and/or federal level. This struggle has continued for 100 years, now, and there is every indication that it will continue somewhat in this same manner through the next 100 years.
|
Ideological scholarship: |
As the pace of events continues to accelerate during
the 21st century, events will deal with such advocacy scholarship
with increasing brutality. Events will not be kind to those who
sell their intellectual souls for a mess of ideological pottage. |
This is the FUTURECASTS list of 20th century economic policy myths that have been clearly demonstrated to be absurd by the course of events. Please e-mail any additions you might think worthy of this list. |
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2001 Daniel Blatt