BOOK REVIEW
Free Trade Under Fire
by
Douglas A. Irwin
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 4, No. 9, 9/1/02.
Characteristics of modern globalization:
& |
A carefully researched, soundly analyzed defense of free trade - of globalization - and the U.S. role in reducing trade barriers is provided by Douglas A. Irwin in "Free Trade Under Fire." He demonstrates convincingly the economic benefits of free trade, and provides a detailed critique of the objections raised in behalf of protectionist and anti trade ideological causes. In addition, he concludes:
|
Protectionist policies will directly harm employment in other domestic industries by raising their production costs, in addition to forcing consumers to pay a higher price for the products they buy. |
To provide a true picture of U.S. participation in international trade, Irwin does not rely on GDP figures, since these include such expanding non-traded or lightly traded sectors as government and many private services. A more accurate picture is provided by the "merchandise production" figures.
Merchandise exports rose from about 15% of merchandise
production in 1970 to almost 40% in 1999. Because of peculiarities in the
statistical data, Irwin points out that this does not mean that 40% of
merchandise production was actually exported - but it does demonstrate that the
proportion of merchandise production exported considerably more that doubled in
the three decades.
This was not the case before 1980. Thus,
"protectionist policies will directly harm employment in other domestic
industries by raising their production costs, in addition to forcing consumers
to pay a higher price for the products they buy." |
Growing levels of direct foreign investment,
however, increasingly confuse these figures. The U.S. owns growing interests
in foreign corporations that export to the U.S., and foreigners own growing
interests in U.S. domestic corporations. |
|
Considerable skepticism is justified when evaluating the official trade figures. |
Moreover, there is "vertical specialization," as components and intermediate goods increasingly get processed and shipped back and forth across borders. At least 3% of U.S. imports - $25 billion - "actually represents the value of domestic products that have been exported and then returned to the U.S." after further work abroad. The domestic content of this trade is especially large with Mexico and Canada.
Barbie dolls have similarly divided provenance. Indeed, a
significant percentage of trade is simply the exchange of material between
affiliates of a multinational company. (The pricing of these transfers is hardly
an exact science - and usually errs against high tax jurisdictions.) These
"intrafirm" transactions accounted for 36% of U.S. exports of goods
and 43% of U.S. imports of goods in 1994. |
Public opinion:
& |
Americans view international trade
favorably. Majorities range from 60% to nearly 70% favorable on a variety of
trade questions. Even bigger majorities, however, believe that labor and
environmental standards should be a part of trade agreements, and the public is
evenly divided over "fast track" authority and new initiatives, due to
the belief that trade plays a role in increasing inequalities. & |
Advantages of trade:
& |
The theoretical case and empirical data supporting the benefits of free trade - from the time of Adam Smith to the present - are reviewed by Irwin. The benefits from specialization and the division of labor are obvious and enormous. Also important - if not so obvious - are the benefits of "comparative advantage" that assures that all nations can find advantages in international trade even if none of their producers of goods and services are among the most efficient. |
"Comparative advantage" assures that all nations can find advantages in international trade even if none of their producers of goods and services are among the most efficient.
In addition to direct gains are the indirect gains from the increased productivity of domestic producers and the discipline of import competition imposed on domestic producers with market power.
Also, there are the incalculable benefits to consumers of increased variety and quality increases not reflected in economic statistics.
|
By suddenly opening itself to trade in 1858, for example,
studies have calculated that Japan had a rapid increase in real income of as
much as 65%, Irwin points out. Since almost all nations are today already
engaged in international trade, direct gains from planned further trade
liberalization would be far less dramatic - less than 2% of GDP for most nations
and the world. However, elimination of all remaining trade barriers could as an
immediate impact increase U.S. and world GDP around 6%.
|
The benefits of foreign research and development can be inexpensively acquired by importing pertinent capital goods, intermediate goods, and consumer goods.
In one nation after another, the substantial reduction of trade barriers has led to tripling and quadrupling of productivity growth rates. |
By improving productivity,
international trade raises standards of living. By increasing competition, it forces out the least productive
producers - forces all remaining producers to adopt best practices - and permits
the most successful to expand both domestically and internationally. (The introduction in the U.S. of
Japanese auto production methods and technology in the 1980s is a prime
example.)
While the studies are concededly imprecise, a variety of different
studies using a variety of different methods have indicated substantial benefits
from international trade. "Almost invariably, more open trade policies are
associated with higher per capita income, although the magnitude and
significance of the relationship varied considerably." |
The much maligned McDonalds has set standards for clean restrooms and orderly and pleasant service that domestic competitors have been forced to emulate around the world. |
A direct relationship between investment rates and trade has
also been demonstrated. Since "the share of investment in GDP is positively
correlated with growth in per capita income," there is a relationship
between trade and growth in per capita income - as well as with economic growth
in general. Irwin points to dramatic increases in economic growth rates in
Chile, S. Korea and India after significant reductions in trade barriers. |
The contributions of trade to democratization and peace is far more difficult to prove, but an impressive list of nations have moved towards democratization at some time after trade liberalization - (Chile, Taiwan, S. Korea, Mexico) - and democracies seldom fight with each other.
|
|
There is no connection between trade liberalization and environmental degradation - but there is often a direct relationship between protectionist subsidies and environmental problems.
Logging for timber and timber products is just a minor cause of deforestation in tropical countries.
All too often, environmental concerns are raised by protectionist forces and ideological opponents of capitalism to kill trade liberalization rather than for any legitimate environmental purpose. |
The greatest environmental disasters, Irwin notes, occurred in the old Soviet Union and its satellites. The most polluted cities are in the undeveloped and developing world. "The burning of the Amazon rain forests is largely motivated by local inhabitants clearing land for their own use, not international trade."
There is no connection between trade liberalization and environmental
degradation - but there is often a direct relationship between protectionist
subsidies and environmental problems. Subsidized fishing fleets over fish ocean
fishery stocks. Agricultural subsidies and trade restraints encourage marginal
farming heavily reliant on agrochemicals and intensive animal production
practices and overgrazing. "Countries that have a comparative advantage in
agriculture, whether they are industrialized, such as Canada and Australia, or
developing, such as Argentina and Brazil, do not depend as heavily on
fertilizers and pesticides to maintain output."
Indeed, blocking the timber trade would immediately reduce the value
of the forests, reducing local incentives to properly manage their forest
resources. Taxing timber exports to encourage purchase of value added plywood
and other mill products in Indonesia results in 15% greater use of timber
because of wastage from inefficient Indonesian mills. The inefficiency of local
processors is common in these cases. |
Costs of trade restraints: |
The costs to U.S. consumers from trade
barriers has been calculated at about $32 billion in 1996 - with textile
restraints being the most costly. (This does not include the costs to taxpayers
of subsidies for agriculture and other producers.) "As of the early 1990s,
the United States maintained more than three thousand separate quotas on imports
from more than forty nations." & |
Quotas are actually more costly than tariffs, Irwin points out.
Tariffs at least provide extra revenues for the government and transfer wealth
from domestic consumers to domestic producers. Quotas, on the other hand, increase prices and
transfer wealth to the foreign producers that have the quotas. Such
"rents" from artificial scarcity in textiles amounts to over $6
billion. Sugar quotas cost about $900 million annually - with $500 million
attributable to economic inefficiency and $400 million attributable to quota
rents to foreign exporters.
|
Theoretical advantages of protectionism are generally dubious, Irwin concludes, and are confined at best to narrow situations demanding constant accurate adjustments to shifting markets well beyond the management capabilities of governments.
Free trade is simpler and requires less active political management. It also avoids the buildup of "concentrated political and economic power, not just to do good but also to make costly mistakes" inherent in interventionist policies.
|
|
Free trade is not a magic bullet, the author prudently cautions. There is a wide array of other good government policies that facilitate domestic profit driven, market directed commerce, that are also essential for prosperity. As examples, he mentions rule of law, protection of property rights, fiscal and monetary discipline, police protection, education, infrastructure, and appropriate foreign relations. However, protectionism causes real harm.
|
Effects on employment: |
Trade both destroys and creates jobs. (The exact same thing can
be said about competition in domestic trade.) The number of jobs is determined by the number of
people in the labor force, the business cycle, and labor market policies - not
trade. In fact, between 1994 - when NAFTA was enacted - and 2000, unemployment
fell from 6.1% to 4% - rising thereafter in line with the business cycle
rather than due to trade flows. & |
Formulaic efforts to
calculate the impacts of trade on jobs are convincingly debunked by Irwin. Such calculations
- put forth by a variety of economists - are "bound to
rest on implausible and arbitrary assumptions and the predictions are ultimately
unverifiable" because of the impossibility of isolating trade influences
from the myriad other influences affecting employment.
|
Nations that liberalize trade and thus experience sharp increases in imports as a percentage of GDP also automatically enjoy similar sharp increases in exports - and gain the benefits of export diversification in addition. On the other hand, nations like Brazil that continuously restrain imports fail to increase exports despite strenuous efforts. |
Restraints on imports invariably restrain exports. There is a fundamental tie between exports and imports - working through various mechanisms such as monetary exchange rates. Irwin explains how nations that liberalize trade and thus experience sharp increases in imports as a percentage of GDP also automatically enjoy similar sharp increases in exports - and gain the benefits of export diversification in addition. On the other hand, nations like Brazil that continuously restrain imports fail to increase exports despite strenuous efforts.
This inherent connection between exports and imports is called "the Lerner symmetry," after a young economist who first clearly demonstrated the phenomenon.
|
Moreover, trade restraints raise the price of intermediate goods, adversely affecting jobs in pertinent industries. The high price of sugar has been estimated to have cost almost 9,000 jobs in food manufacturing and refining - forcing some heavy users of sugar to close down U.S. operations and expand Canadian operations. Periodic trade restraints on electronic components like flat panel displays and computer chips have chased many computer manufacturers out of the country. Steel restraints have a depressing impact on steel users.
Unfortunately, "those seeking to limit trade tend to be more
vocal than those who benefit from open markets.." |
The contention that a trade deficit costs jobs is also debunked by Irwin.
|
|
The decline in employment in manufacturing during these last three decades has nevertheless been dramatic. While the nominal loss has only been from 19.4 million jobs to 18.5 million, as a percentage of the workforce the decline has been from 27% to 14%. However, real manufacturing output rose 40% in the 1990s alone, "and has declined only slightly as a share of GDP when measured at constant prices." (There is no evidence of the feared "hollowing out" of U.S. industrial capacity.)
The author points out that most of the trade deficit is due to the import of mineral fuels. The deficit in manufacturing is actually very small.
|
|
Consumers pay $24 billion annually to protect about 170,000 textile jobs - or about $140,000 per job. The cost is $350,000 per job in protected machine tool manufacturing and $600,000 in sugar.
"Real compensation" is determined by productivity and has closely tracked productivity gains for decades. Trade has a substantial positive impact on productivity, and thus is responsible for a substantial fraction of the U.S. increase in average real compensation.
The U.S. actually imports very little from low wage nations, so these imports cannot be a major contributor to wage inequality. The major factor has been "the spectacular increase in the labor market return to education," due mainly to technological change. |
Nor are many high wage jobs being lost to import competition. On average, they are low skilled, low wage jobs such as in the apparel industry.
U.S. exports, however, tend to be "more skill-intensive
manufactured products, such as aircraft, construction machinery, engines and
turbines, and industrial chemicals."
Trade restraints can, of course, benefit highly paid unionized workers by
sustaining their union wage premiums. This is the case in the auto and steel
industries. Trade restraints have NOT been successful in increasing employment in these
industries, but has been successful in maintaining the union wage premiums of
those employed. The industries, however, remain in chronic difficulty due to
world wide overcapacity driven by similar protectionist policies in many other
nations. |
Displaced workers: |
Help for workers displaced by imports may be
politically essential to reduce opposition to free trade, Irwin concedes.
However, it is not always that easy to distinguish between workers displaced by
imports and those displaced for other reasons. He asks: "[D]o we need
special policies for trade-displaced workers?" & |
Trade is " a small factor in the
displacement of labor," compared to domestic influences. Since NAFTA, U.S. employment has risen by more than
10 million. Although monthly employment turnover in the U.S. exceeds 2 million,
only about 40,000 per year qualified for cash and training trade adjustment
assistance. (The "giant sucking sound" of jobs heading south of the
border never occurred.) |
Unfair competition: |
Procedures have been established to counter
unfair competition subsidized by foreign governments. Countervailing duties
in the amount of the subsidy margin can be imposed by these procedures in
accordance with international trade agreements. & |
Since dumping is judged by comparing any individual price in the U.S. to the average price in the exporters home market, dumping is almost always found, and the dumping margins are inflated.
The procedure is so chilling, that imports invariably fall substantially as soon as a complaint is filed, since importers fear becoming liable if the complaint is upheld.
Most cases filed actually end in negotiated agreements imposing artificially higher prices.
Unsurprisingly, other countries have quickly learned this game, and U.S. exporters are increasingly targeted by antidumping complaints.
|
However, the antidumping law is the preferred remedy against competing imports - also in accordance with international treaty agreements.
Dumping is defined as a lower price in the U.S. market than in the domestic
market. Import duties may be imposed to offset the difference.
A Commerce Dep't. Inspector General found - in 84 steel industry
complaints filed in June, 1992 - that the adjudicating agency "adopted
several controversial and confusing policies that undermined the principles of
transparency and consistency --- [and were] not only inconsistent with past
practice, but were also applied inconsistently from one case to the next." The policies applied "made reporting more onerous for respondents, caused
confusion among analysts, and made [the] decision appear arbitrary, even to its
own staff." |
The vast majority of cases do not involve foreign exporters with anything near the market power for a successful predatory pricing effort. |
After all, as Irwin points out about price discrimination, "charging
different prices in different markets, is a normal business practice and an
accepted feature of domestic competition." Only if the action is
"predatory" or in some way "anticompetitive" is it harmful.
However, the laws are not aimed at such harmful actions. They are thus apparent
efforts to protect domestic businesses. |
The escape clause: |
Temporary nondiscriminatory tariffs are
permitted under international agreements - for 4 to 8 years - to provide
some relief for domestic industries unable to compete with imports. The
standards for use of this remedy are much stiffer than under the
antidumping procedures, and so it is seldom used. & |
Justification for this remedy is provided by the practical recognition
of political necessity. Most nations would be wary of any trade agreements if
they had no power to respond to domestic political pressures. "Some form of
safeguards seems to be a political necessity." |
History and political theory: |
Irwin reviews the political theory and
history of trade policy going back to the 1888 election between Grover
Cleveland and Benjamin Harrison. There are many reasons for the political bias
in favor of protectionism - the most basic of which is that "the
benefits of trade protection are highly concentrated, while the costs are widely
diffused." & |
"The benefits of trade protection are highly concentrated, while the costs are widely diffused." |
Thus, even though sugar import restraints cost consumers almost twice
as much as a small handful of large growers gain, the cost is only about $7 per
consumer, while some individual growers reap millions. It was thus worth while for sugar
producer political action committees to make more than $1.2 million in campaign
contributions for the 2000 election campaign. |
Trade policy is controlled by Congress under Article 1, Section
8 of the Constitution. In the past, Congress set trade policy with little
Presidential input. (This led to the disastrous trade war of the 1920s,
culminating in the 1930 Smoot-Hawley Tariff that played such a major role in
driving the Great Depression down and then blocking recovery.) Today, Congress
still controls trade policy. However, it grants the President negotiating
authority - imposes conditions - rejects or approves the result - and enacts
procedures offering domestic industries relief from foreign competition. |
|
The executive branch provided a focus for nationwide export interests whereas Congress had always served to focus on narrow statewide protectionist interests.
The trade wars of the 1920s and 1930s began to be recognized as having played a major role in impoverishing and embittering the world and driving nations into the hands of aggressive despots. |
The 1934
Reciprocal Trade Agreement Act, championed by Sec. of State Cordell Hull,
brought the first crack in the tariff wall.
Although agreements were reached with most of the major trading partners of the
U.S. by WW-II, tariff reductions were modest and results were minimal.
Finally, the Cold War brought foreign policy considerations to bear.
Trade liberalization was seen as a practical way to strengthen allies and
support resistance to Communism. The trade wars of the 1920s and 1930s began to
be recognized as having played a major role in impoverishing and embittering the
world and driving nations into the hands of aggressive despots. Cordell Hull -
with a powerful assist from some very harsh history - had won. |
GATT:
& |
The 1947 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade attempted a
multilateral approach to trade liberalization. Trade barriers were significantly
reduced, but existing trade preferences - such as those within the British
Empire - remained, and great latitude was maintained for nations wishing to
maintain trade restrictions. Quantitative restrictions and exchange controls
remained in wide use, but discriminatory practices between imports from various
nations and between domestic products and imports were banned. & |
The treaty successfully reduced trade barriers, established rules
governing trade, and created a forum for further negotiations. But efforts to
establish an International Trade Organization failed. |
"No independent power resides in GATT itself, which essentially relies on the good will of the signatories." |
GATT is self enforcing. Aggrieved nations are authorized to
suspend their obligations to offending nations. "No independent power
resides in GATT itself, which essentially relies on the good will of the
signatories." |
An expanded antidumping remedy to a large extent placed the authority to impose protectionist restraints into the hands of the private interests seeking protection. |
With Congress back in the act, however, protections from trade injury began to be expanded. In the 1974 Trade Act, the U.S. International Trade Commission was authorized to grant relief in cases where imports were a "substantial cause" of injury. In Section 301 of the Act, the U.S. Trade Representative was authorized to negotiate on behalf of U.S. exporters aggrieved by actions of foreign nations, and the President was authorized to impose retaliatory duties against offending countries that don't reach a satisfactory settlement of trade disputes.
Since exporters could use this power to pry open foreign markets, many
have lost interest in further trade liberalization - shifting political power
again back in favor of protectionist interests. This export procedure faded in
importance after 1994, when such disputes came under the jurisdiction of the
World Trade Organization. (Section 301 complaints continue to be filed, but a
substantial majority are referred to the WTO.) |
Preferential trade agreements: |
Bilateral and regional trade
agreements increased in importance in the 1980s. The Caribbean Basin
Initiative, agreements with Israel, Canada, Mexico and Jordan have been
concluded by the U.S., and a Western Hemisphere agreement is under negotiation.
As of 2000, the WTO reported 114 regional trade agreements in effect worldwide. & |
Article 23 of GATT permits these agreements, but they are
essentially discriminatory. Whether they on balance increase or harm economic
welfare is a complex problem that economists have not been able to crack.
However, some of these agreements have foreign policy objectives as well as
economic objectives. |
The Uruguay Round: |
New types of trade restrictions - such as
"voluntary export restraints" - were blossoming in the 1980s in
response to GATT. Nevertheless, the Uruguay Round was a major success. Besides
extending trade liberalization, it created the World Trade Organization
("WTO") and strengthened the dispute settlement process. Average
tariff levels in developed countries were brought down to 3.8% - developing
countries to 12.3%. & |
Developing nations reasonably view labor standards and environmental standard conditions as weapons used to continue to deny their exports access to developed nation markets. |
This round also began to address trade in agricultural goods,
textiles and apparel, services, investment, and intellectual property. It
attempts the removal of non tariff barriers to agricultural trade, but tariffs
and export subsidies remain very high. The next round - the Doha Round - is
expected to begin the politically explosive task of reducing them. |
The WTO: |
Like the GATT, the WTO has virtually no independent power.
The member governments still make trade policy and write the rules governing
trade. The WTO can't even comment on these policies. & |
So, what does it do? Mainly, it provides a forum for discussing trade policy, and assists in the resolution of trade disputes. It has just a small budget and staff - most of whom are translators.
With modest funding and staffing and limited powers, the WTO has the
vital mission of keeping the international trading system functioning smoothly. |
The strengthening of the dispute settlement process was predominantly a U.S. initiative - pushed predominantly by Congress. |
The dispute settlement process formalizes and strengthens the
process previously developed in an ad hoc manner under GATT. As before, if
initial informal efforts to resolve a dispute fail, a panel of experts is
convened to arbitrate a dispute, interpret GATT rules and issue a finding as to
whether the trade measures in question conform to GATT rules. However, under WTO
procedures, there are specific time tables and no nation is permitted to block
either the formation of the panel or the adoption of a panel report. An appeal
on questions of law and legal interpretation is available.
|
The WTO cannot force any changes. However, the threat of retaliatory action by complaining nations and the threat to reputation have proven to be potent - even if far from perfect - remedies. |
The remedies thus remain self enforcing. All member nations,
including the U.S., retain complete control over their policies. The WTO cannot
force any changes. However, the threat of retaliatory action by complaining
nations and the threat to reputation have proven to be potent - even if
far from perfect - remedies.
|
A General Accounting Office ('GAO") evaluation of the first five years
of the WTO dispute resolution process - with the U.S. winning some and losing
some - concluded that most dispute resolutions were beneficial and that
"none of the changes the United States has made in response to WTO disputes
have had major policy or commercial impact to date, though stakes in several
were important." |
Environmental conditions: |
The question of whether WTO rules take
precedence over domestic environmental, health and safety regulations has
been especially contentious. Organizations like Ralph Nader's Global Trade Watch
charge that "in the WTO forum, global commerce takes precedence over
everything - democracy, public health, equity, the environment, food safety and
more." & |
Most of the few WTO disputes dealing with environmental or health issues merely reviewed whether regulations were implemented in a discriminatory manner. |
Irwin charges that this is a considerable exaggeration. The GAO examination
of this issue concluded that "WTO rulings to date against U.S.
environmental measures have not weakened U.S. environmental protections."
Indeed, as of 1999, fewer than 10 of the more than 140 WTO disputes dealt with
environmental or health issues. Of these, most merely reviewed whether
regulations were being implemented in a discriminatory manner. |
The WTO specifically approved reformulated gas requirements - but not the discriminatory application. |
In the Reformulated Gas case - which Nader's Global Trade Watch points to as an example of the WTO threat to national environmental standards and sovereignty - the ruling was merely that the U.S. must apply its regulations in a nondiscriminatory way. Nondiscrimination is a policy the U.S. strongly supports as clearly in its best interests.
Indeed, in testimony before Congress, an EPA administrator admitted
that the more stringent application of the rule to imports was intentional - a
deliberate discrimination - in an effort to help domestic refiners. The WTO
specifically approved reformulated gas requirements - but not the discriminatory
application. |
In the Tuna-Dolphin case, the WTO ruled against U.S. efforts to ban the import of tuna caught with purse seine fishing nets or other means that also sweep up many dolphins. Tuna fishing nations resented this unilateral effort to dictate extraterritorially their domestic production methods. The dolphins were neither U.S. domestic resources nor endangered species, and the U.S. was not authorized by GATT to dictate production methods extraterritorially.
Actually, this dispute took place and was resolved several years prior
to the initiation of the WTO. It was rendered moot by an international treaty
under which the nine major tuna fishing nations agreed to dolphin-safe
production methods. Instead of attempting to dictate to other nations by a U.S.
import ban, the U.S. negotiated an international treaty which proved far more
effective than the unilateral effort. |
|
The WTO ruled that the shrimp measure was justified under GATT "relating to the conservation of exhaustible natural resources," but that it had been implemented in a discriminatory manner favoring Western Hemisphere producers. |
In the Shrimp-Turtle case, a similar production methods dispute
did take place under WTO procedures. The U.S. tried to force foreign shrimp
trawlers to use turtle excluder devices by banning shrimp imports that were not
produced in a turtle-safe manner.
The U.S. and the complaining South East Asian and Indian Ocean nations
have since negotiated treaties for nondiscriminatory application of the ban.
Nonetheless, this case remains controversial because the original WTO panel
ruled that the pertinent environmental rules violated GATT, and the appellate
body overrule of the decision seemed to some as due to outside pressure. |
The product-process issue: |
Restraints based on the methods of
production remain controversial. Many undeveloped nations fear that
anti-process regulations based on environmental and labor standards will be set beyond
their means of compliance and used to block their exports. This will be one of
the more difficult issues raised in future negotiations. |
Unilateral bans based on methods of production are not only
resented, they are ineffective, since the banned product simply goes elsewhere
to be replaced by product produced by acceptable means. Both tuna and shrimp are
fungible commodities. The proper and effective approach in these cases is
through negotiated treaties. |
|
Illegal trade:
& |
Of courses, not all trade restraints are bad.
Nations are still free to agree to appropriate trade restraint treaties. From
the fight against the slave trade in the 19th century to the modern ban on
chlorofluorocarbons, such treaties have their place. But some may be bad policy. |
Health and safety regulations: |
The beef hormones case
demonstrates the difficulty of distinguishing appropriate health and safety
restraints from regulatory protectionism. Europe's
restrictions on beef from cattle fattened with the use of synthetic hormones
affected over $100 million in U.S. exports. There is no question of
discrimination, since the restrictions were applied uniformly to both domestic
and imported beef. & |
Europe did not extent the ban to pork products - which are produced at competitive prices in Europe whereas European cattle are not competitive. |
The science on the subject uniformly found no evidence that the use of
these hormones was unsafe. Far greater levels of the hormone are found naturally
in such products as eggs, cabbage, broccoli and soybean oil. Furthermore, Europe
did not extent the ban to pork products - which are produced at competitive
prices in Europe whereas European cattle are not competitive.
|
Labor standards:
& |
Low wages reflect low labor productivity, Irwin points out. There is a strong relationship between labor costs per worker and value added per worker in manufacturing.
|
Undeveloped nations export goods from unskilled labor-intensive industries because those are the only industries they have. |
Thus, there has been no "giant sucking sound" of U.S. jobs
flowing to Mexico - or India or other undeveloped nations, although some
industry reshuffling does occur in the ordinary course of economic fluctuations.
Multinational corporations have found that "you get what you pay for: low
wages imply a less productive workforce." |
The very low turnover rates - "quit" rates - in multinational facilities is convincing proof that these facilities are in fact substantial improvements on the employment alternatives in undeveloped nations. |
Objections on humanitarian grounds to the low wages and 'sweatshop" conditions in undeveloped nations has led some multinationals to make improvements, but this has had little overall impact on conditions in these nations. Only economic development can provide the higher productivity that will broadly improve labor conditions - and foreign trade and investment are important components of such development. Irwin points to the very low turnover rates - "quit" rates - in multinational facilities as convincing proof that these facilities are in fact substantial improvements on the employment alternatives in undeveloped nations.
|
You can't increase labor standards in poor nations by excluding their exports - you can only do that by accepting their exports. |
Just as trade policy is an inefficient instrument for
environmental objectives - it is an inefficient instrument for raising labor
standards. Irwin convincingly stresses that you can't increase labor standards
in poor nations by excluding their exports - you can only do that by accepting
their exports. |
Since only about 5% of working children are employed in export sectors, a ban would just shift them to other sectors where pay and conditions would be worse - or leave them to starve without support.
The most effective instrument against child labor is economic development. "Child labor virtually disappears once a country's per capita income reaches $5,000." |
There are manifold problems in defining labor standards. Irwin
notes that the U.S. has rejected a standard on employment discrimination based
on sex or religion for fear this will undermine affirmative action policies. It
has rejected a standard on union rights because it has been interpreted as
prohibiting the hiring of replacement workers during a strike. |
The International Labor Organization is obviously the appropriate body for dealing with international labor standards, Irwin contends. It has more appropriate enforcement procedures - which are open to NGO and private as well as government participation. The WTO has neither the expertise nor an effective instrument for dealing with labor standards problems, since trade sanctions are a blunt instrument that hurts the people they ostensibly are intended to help.
It is apparent that labor unions stand opposed to most measures that would increase trade with undeveloped nations. They favor attaching all manner of labor and environmental conditions to trade agreements - not because of the merits of the conditions but just as makeweights.
|
Benefits of reciprocal agreements: |
The case for free trade is unilateral.
As Irwin points out, nations benefit from both exports and imports. The imposition of import
restraints is the economic equivalent of shooting yourself in the foot. & |
However, reciprocity is politically practical, because it creates a powerful interest group of exporters to counter protectionist influence. Obviously, there are gains from exports as well as imports. Both are win-win activities. Thus, much rides on the continued success of trade liberalizing treaty negotiations. |
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2002 Dan Blatt