BOOK REVIEW
The Health Care Mess
by
Drs. Julius B. Richmond & Rashi Fein
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 9, No. 9, 9/1/07
A) The Dysfunctional Health Care System
The third party payer system mess:
& |
A useful history of modern health care delivery mechanisms in the U.S. and an
account of the dysfunctional mess that has evolved comprises the bulk of
"The Health Care Mess: How We Got Into It and What It Will Take To Get
Out," by Drs. Julius B. Richmond and Rashi Fein. & |
The health care system has become the most heavily regulated major segment of the American economy, and has become increasingly distorted by seven decades of increasingly intrusive government policy. |
Exhibiting a deplorable ignorance of basic economics, however, the authors repeatedly attribute this mess to private enterprise market failure. They use this "market failure" as the rationale for advocating the total displacement of the current system by a government administered universal health care alternative.
As their own history demonstrates, the health care system
has become the most heavily regulated major segment of the American economy, and
has become increasingly distorted by seven decades of increasingly intrusive
government policy. |
The authors use the failures of partial government administered alternatives as reasons for expanding reliance on government administered alternatives - ultimately extending to total reliance on government administered health care alternatives. |
This is hardly a "market" system any longer. It is
already predominantly a third party payer system. Pervasive third
party payer systems inherently destroy all the cost containment capabilities of
the market. As the authors show, all administered substitutes for market cost containment have failed - as
they always do. The lack of cost containment is thus unsurprisingly undermining
the nation's current health care system (and will ultimately undermine any
alternative government administered universal system).
The authors view as unfortunate that doubts about the accuracy of cost estimates are now far more widespread than in the 1960s prior to actual experience with Medicare and Medicaid.
|
Rapidly increasing health insurance obligations have become a major headache that businesses and unions alike would now love to offload onto the taxpayers. |
Health insurance has been a major asset to labor leaders and businesses in providing funds to manage and benefits with which to assure member and employee loyalty. However, rapidly increasing health insurance obligations have become a major headache that businesses and unions alike would now love to offload onto the taxpayers. A government administered comprehensive social insurance scheme would involve "a massive redirection of dollars now flowing through the system," involving major increases in taxes offset by reductions in business costs.
However, the vast majority of Americans are currently insured and are not convinced that their coverage would be improved by a universal government social insurance system, the authors concede. The authors also recognize that when a massive universal social insurance scheme wends its way through the legislative meat grinder, what comes out may not resemble the ideal proposals envisioned going in. Thus, they believe that the way forward will likely be by means of an incremental approach that ultimately becomes universal. |
B) Universal Health Care Proposal
Implementing universal health care: |
A universal federal health care system is
the remedy recommended. The authors note that the nation may not be
ready to swallow this whole hog, so suggest that the objective be reached by
intermediate phases. & |
The authors reject a "welfare" approach that would cover the neediest first, since this would lack the political power of a middle class entitlement. |
An incremental approach can, of course, proceed in
many ways. The authors note that Medicare, Medicaid and the State Children's
Health Insurance Program were all enacted in stages and can continue to be
expanded in stages. In order to minimize future political debate over future
incremental expansions of the system, the authors suggest that all the phases of
an incremental scheme be
enacted at once with a timetable for implementation or with stated triggering
mechanisms. (Who could need further debate?) |
All that is needed, the authors confidently assert, is the political will. |
The authors acknowledge the complexity of the
enterprise, but express not the slightest doubt about the ability of
government to administer it. All that is needed, they confidently assert, is the
political will.
|
Several issues are expressly recognized by the authors.
|
Medicare for all: |
Two reform plans are offered by
the authors. One would be immediately comprehensive, and the other would
incrementally become comprehensive. & |
A single payer social insurance approach - a "Medicare for all" - like the Canadian system - supported by tax revenues - would simplify enrollment and would be the most efficient to administer.
|
|
The rate of cost increases would be modest, the authors assert. At the expected modest rate of cost increase, the new system would ultimately cost less than the current system while achieving universal coverage. The authors promise regionalization and rationalization of health care delivery - but offer no specifics.
|
A mere expansion of the FEHB program: |
The system would
be analogous to the Federal Employees Health
Benefits (FEHB) program, the authors assert reassuringly. & |
The national system would formulate plans and direct system modifications. It would develop budgets for the health care delivery system. It would require constant surveillance of costs and the quality of services and extensive administrative oversight to assure proper provider conduct. |
This would indeed be a good starting point for a national health care program.
However, the authors seem to expect that the national system would do much more than just pay some or all of the bills. It would formulate plans and direct system modifications. It would develop budgets for the health care delivery system. It would require constant surveillance of costs and the quality of services and extensive administrative oversight to assure proper provider conduct - especially willingness to accept open enrollment of all applicants rather than screening for pre-existing health problems.
|
Rather than a lightly regulated FEHB program, the authors want to impose extensive constraints on for-profit activities to limit further expansion of the for-profit sector, to hold them accountable, to direct their efforts towards meeting social needs, and to tax them for the funds needed to cover the massive government administrative expenses that all this obviously entails. |
The expansion of for-profit health care providers has
been detrimental to the health care system in many ways, the authors assert. They
recognize that the for-profits are now so extensive a part of the system that it
will not be practical to proceed without them. However, rather than a lightly
regulated FEHB program, the authors want to impose extensive constraints on
for-profit activities to limit further expansion of the for-profit sector, to
hold them accountable, to direct their efforts towards meeting social needs, and
to tax them for the funds needed to cover the massive government administrative
expenses that all this obviously entails. The authors are anxious to impose new
tax burdens on the for-profit sector - to use for-profits as cash cows for all kinds of purposes.
|
The authors assert that there can be too much choice - that it can become confusing and paralyzing. |
The public's desire for choice is just an obstacle that gets in the way of the authors' grand plan. The authors recognize that people want the freedom to choose, but argue that there can be too much choice - that it can become confusing and paralyzing. They express concern that a varied menu system - such as is provided for government employees under FEHB - would be too complicated for many people to navigate, so government should impose a one size fits all approach on everyone.
|
Increased administrative complexity is
correctly feared by the authors. A government social insurance system that
offered choice and relied on a welfare component would indeed add administrative
complexity. & |
Organization of universal health care: |
Thus, it is Medicare and Medicaid expansion
rather
than FEHB program expansion that the authors really advocate. & |
Medicare and Medicaid could be expanded by phases - probably by age - to ultimately cover everyone. The first phase would probably start with children, since children need the least health care and would provide the biggest expansion for the least financial commitment. An alternative is to simply start with the "uninsured." Coverage of the uninsured is a major intermediate goal.
|
The authors provide nothing but boxes on an organization chart. |
And just how is this vast complex enterprise to be
run? The authors provide nothing but boxes on an organization chart.
|
The organization chart would be headed by:
This commission would administer the federal health insurance system and recommend funding and benefit levels to Congress. It would receive system funds and disburse them to insurers on behalf of enrollees. It would monitor and assure quality of care and the efficient administration of the system.
|
For cost containment, the authors offer nothing other than the common government budgeting procedures that have repeatedly proved no more than minimally adequate in other contexts far less complex than a national health care system. |
Cost containment is a recognized difficulty. However, the authors offer nothing other than the common government budgeting procedures that have repeatedly proved no more than minimally adequate in other contexts far less complex than a national health care system.
The authors apparently feel that even all this will not be enough to keep the boards busy. They view this vast, complex budgeting and planning effort for this vast complex nationwide health care system as an opportunity to encourage debates about resource allocations and system benefits. Along with "nonpartisan" professionals, the boards would include members who "represent" the public. The boards would provide opportunities for "substantial public input."
|
Funding will be through the tax system. |
Funding, too, is just a matter of boxes on the organization chart. During the phase-in period, there may be various funding mechanisms employed. However, ultimately, it is the IRS that is the agency naturally to be tasked with administering the collection of funds just as it does for Social Security and Medicare. Whatever the mix of individual and/or employer premium and/or tax payments and/or tax credits and/or government subsidies employed, the IRS has the data needed to administer a suitably graduated system of payments. Ultimately, the IRS provides "an administratively simple way" to achieve universality and end the current employment based system that so clearly benefits most those in the highest income brackets.
|
C) The History of the U.S. Health Care System
Establishment of the third party payer system: |
The road to the
destruction of the health care market was indeed paved with good intentions. & |
The Social Security Act of 1935 provided grants to the states for crippled children and maternal and child health care programs. The federal government became increasingly involved in funding medical research through the National Institutes of Health. By 1965, the national government was providing $1.3 billion for medical research - 87% of the total. The effort was not free from political influence. The government began picking the winners and losers.
Medical school administration and the teaching role of the medical schools
were losers as funding by the government increased the
relative importance of the research role. Researchers had divided loyalties.
Many were more concerned with satisfying their government grantors than with the
administration of their medical school or the teaching of their students. |
Private insurance approaches had concentrated
coverage on hospital care - the expensive part of health care. There was
competition between the not-for-profit Blue Cross insurers that offered broad
coverage based on a community rating approach and for-profit insurers that
offered lower premium coverage for lower risk groups. |
|
Group plans had both advantages and disadvantages.
However, small firms and their insurers could not take
the risks of some catastrophic loss afflicting a member of a small group. Small groups or
groups consisting of many high risk individuals find it difficult to sustain the
subsidy for high risk individuals. |
Since insurance covered hospital care, there was a "perverse incentive to hospitalize individuals." |
Tax breaks from and after WW-II, both for the
employer and employee, were powerful incentives for the inclusion of health insurance as a
benefit of employment. By 1951, 77 million people were covered by some form of
health insurance. |
The grossly inefficient use of emergency rooms for primary care of the uninsured became standard practice. |
Supply and demand apply to the health care market
as to other markets. The spread of insurance increased demand into a market with
a sticky supply curve. It takes a long time to increase the supply of health
care professionals. Health care costs were soon rising rapidly. This stimulated
a buildup in health care resources and an upgrading in technology that added to
costs. (In other industries, technological advances decrease costs.) This in
turn increased the importance of insurance.
|
The Kennedy
administration came into office in 1961 with a varied agenda, including the
expansion of government health programs to include Medicare for individuals 65
and older. |
|
Then Medicare was enacted under the Lyndon Johnson
administration. This was intended from the beginning not just to provide hospital
coverage for the elderly, but as a cornerstone on which to build an
"inclusive universal program" of health care. The authors go at some
length into the political debate.
The authors point out that Medicare subsidizes access to the traditional health care system - acting much like traditional insurance. The legislation specifically forbids federal government "supervision or control over the practice of medicine, the manner in which medical services are provided, and the administration or operation of medical facilities."
|
Heath care entitlements affected and distorted health care delivery systems and generated additional inflation in health care costs, while leaving significant numbers still without health care coverage and increasing the expense of obtaining it. |
Again, the noxious unintended consequences were
not long in making an appearance. The 1960s and 1970s were an age of inflation
and societal flux. Defects in the program became increasingly apparent as the
program affected and distorted health care delivery systems and generated
additional inflation in health care costs, while leaving significant numbers
still without health care coverage and increasing the expense of obtaining it.
These programs immediately greatly increased demand for health care
services, but supply increases were far slower to come on line. Health care cost
inflation quickly surged to double digit rates, far exceeding even the substantial
rates of general inflation of the 1970s. The issue of access to health care was
perforce replaced by the issues of cost inflation and methods of restraining
cost inflation. |
Regulations added to costs and caused much dissatisfaction among patients and providers alike. |
Inevitably, administered cost control alternatives - price controls and the rationing of care - were attempted - and just as inevitably experienced little success. The problems of third party payer systems were becoming ever more evident. Regulations added to costs and caused much dissatisfaction among patients and providers alike.
|
"Medicine, after all, is an art as well as a science; physicians and nurses must exercise judgment, and the predominant 'culture' can and does influence behavior." |
Health Maintenance Organizations (HMOs) - a form of prepaid group practice of which the Kaiser Permanente health program was an outstanding example - were encouraged beginning with Nixon administration legislation passed in 1973. Managed care sought to restrain cost growth by administered methods. However, it took a long time and much additional legislation before HMOs really took off. Employers desperate to contain health benefit costs pushed employee enrollment.
HMOs had considerable success in reducing hospital utilization. However, patients ultimately rebelled against the choice restraints and the effort failed. As the authors cogently explain:
|
Swamped by unintended consequences:
& |
Again, there were unintended consequences. The impact extended beyond the intended restraint in hospital utilization to medical school curricula and "relationships between medical education and the world of practice both in and outside their affiliated hospitals."
|
Efforts to create a comprehensive national health care system
or to enact further incremental expansion of coverage continued. The favored
comprehensive approach involved mandated employer health insurance supplemented
with subsidy programs. Other approaches included tax credit encouragement for
health insurance or straightforward national social insurance supported directly
by taxes. & |
Experience with the inadequacies of entitlement cost projections undermined the case for expanded entitlements. The Medicare program that was supposed to only cost $9 billion by 1990 cost $90 billion, instead - only about half the increase being accounted for by the general rate of inflation.
Congress had surrendered an increasingly significant segment of the power of the purse to forces outside its control. |
However, the issue of "cost control" increasingly
took top priority away from "access." Big government in general and
entitlements in particular lost their charm in the 1970s and 1980s as the costs
greatly exceeded expectations and the results frequently fell short. Proponents
of national health insurance began to supplement their case by arguing that
after an initial increase in costs, national health insurance with suitable
budget controls would ultimately prove less costly than the mess that had been
created. |
The costs of providing for the indigent uninsured were largely shifted to the insured - pushing up insurance premiums and pricing more people out of the insurance market. Gaps grew in what Medicare and Medicaid provided for and what was needed. |
There were yet more unintended consequences. The costs of providing for the indigent uninsured were largely shifted to the insured - pushing up insurance premiums and pricing more people out of the insurance market. Gaps grew in what Medicare and Medicaid provided for and what was needed. Administered cost controls proved - as always - ineffective, unacceptable - and expensive to administer.
All of this, the authors stress, does not negate the vast advances in
the quality and delivery of health care services since WW-II. Both access and
outcomes have improved immensely. |
Hospital stays were extended, tests proliferated and were repeated, new equipment was obtained regardless of community need, debts were incurred to be financed by future grants and government reimbursements, etc. "Cream skimming" and "cherry picking" became increasingly familiar means for insurers and providers to reduce costs and increase profits. |
As soon as market cost constraints were removed by the flood of
government money, costs exploded in innumerable ways summarized by the authors.
Hospital stays were extended, tests proliferated and were repeated, new
equipment was obtained regardless of community need, debts were incurred to be
financed by future grants and government reimbursements, etc. "Cream
skimming" and "cherry picking" became increasingly familiar means
for insurers and providers to reduce costs and increase profits.
Actually, most of the advances in health care have come from promotion
of healthy living habits and disease prevention rather than from improvements in
clinical care. In recognition of this, the U.S. Surgeon General's office has
since 1979 continuously encouraged the study and promotion of methods of disease
control and prevention. The attack on smoking and the substantial reduction in
public exposure to smoking and passive smoking is highlighted by the authors.
(Other programs have emphasized safety equipment - helmets for cyclists, seat
belts for automobile passengers, etc.) |
The supply side of the economic picture naturally came in for
considerable attention. The 1963 Health Professions Educational Assistance Act
provided construction funds for schools that committed themselves to increased
medical student enrollments. Scholarships in return for public service were
provided under the National Health Service Corps program. States, too, provided
funds for these purposes. |
Studies revealed wide and disturbing variances in the number of procedures performed, practice methods, and the length of hospital stays. |
Medical school curricula also underwent significant changes, as
outlined by the authors. The digital revolution impacted all aspects of medical
science, practice and facilities. There was much ferment as different approaches
were tried. Through it all, the performance of students, teachers, researchers
and physicians was by all measures more than maintained. |
Physician "oversupply" concerns appeared in many specialties in the 1980s, replacing physician shortage concerns. Even with respect to the acknowledged "sticky" supply curve of the health care market, administered alternatives - "rational planning" - were proving less than satisfactory.
|
|
Continuing medical education requirements proliferated to
assure maintenance of appropriate skills in a rapidly advancing medical world.
This was yet one more regulatory burden for physicians. Much of this education
was sponsored by pharmaceutical firms and was held in luxurious locations -
raising obvious conflicts of interest. |
The rise of for-profits: |
Government and not-for-profit institution
dominated health care delivery up until WW-II. The health care market was just
about 4.5% of GDP. This all changed after WW-II. & |
An increase in for-profit hospitals came first. With Medicaid, there was an increase in for profit nursing homes. Then there was the "corporatization of medical practice." While concentrating on fending off government control of medical practice, many doctors - without a fight - now surrendered control of their medical practice to corporations. This, the authors assert, was a great failure of the American Medical Association.
|
The influence and power of the AMA and other medical associations was soon in decline. Of course, many physicians became important entrepreneurs and administrators in this growing for-profit sector. Medical students and physicians began enrolling in schools of business administration. However, they faced inevitable conflicts of interest between their roles as cost controllers and providers of health care services. As doctors, they were obliged to support clinical freedom, but as corporate executives, they were obliged to constrain clinical decisions to control costs.
|
|
The for-profits at least countered tendencies towards "over-doctoring." By constraining hospital stays and diagnostic testing, they had major impacts on costs. |
The corporatization of health care practice was greatly facilitated
by the rise of third party payer systems, the authors acknowledge. Physicians
were increasingly employees or at least partially dependent on salary,
capitation or other contract arrangements. |
The cost containment crisis: |
Nevertheless, third party payers now
dominated the demand side of the market, removing market mechanisms for constraining rising costs. & |
Indeed, all the
incentives were on the other side since rising costs increased revenues and
profits. The authors view this as a weakness in market mechanisms (thus again demonstrating their abysmal ignorance of basic economics). |
Patients became mere onlookers in the battles between employers, insurers, government payers, and providers. |
Patients experienced discontinuities in care as dissatisfied employers shifted insurers and managed care entities. Patients became mere onlookers in the battles between employers, insurers, government payers, and providers. However, the patients were the "real consumers" of health care.
|
Both the patient and the physician had been rendered relatively powerless by the third party payer system. The employer and insurer sought to protect their interests - interests that frequently were at odds with those of the patient and physician. |
The system was thus inherently dysfunctional. Both the patient
and the physician had been rendered relatively powerless by the third party
payer system. The employer and insurer sought to protect their interests -
interests that frequently were at odds with those of the patient and physician. |
The authors express astonishment at how fast the unintended
consequences evolved - how fast the industry changed in response to the spread
of the third party payer system. It "could not have been anticipated,"
they assert. It could not have been "imagined" how powerless the
medical community would be to oppose the changes. (Nothing demonstrates their
abysmal ignorance of basic economics like these assertions.) |
|
Medical research, too, was inevitably affected by entrepreneurial incentives. Instead of an open academic process, academic researchers began taking out patents and commercializing results. While research efforts continued to achieve great successes, the system was generating conflicts of interest. The entrepreneur-investigator was employee both of a university and a sponsoring commercial establishment.
|
The search for a national solution: |
Growing discontent increased
public pressure for a national solution. & |
The Clinton administration responded - but instead of a simple
single payer national health care system - perhaps an expansion of Medicare - it
engaged in an effort to satisfy the manifold interest groups. The result was
"Hillary care" - a complex monstrosity of employment linked mandates
and regulations. This was rejected not only by Congress, but by the electorate,
too, in the succeeding Congressional elections.
|
However, Congress continued to undertake additional obligations. A
number of initiatives were enacted in succeeding years providing federal
assistance - sometimes through state participation - to uninsured children and
particular groups of patients, and facilitating insurance portability for those
leaving employment positions that had provided insurance. (This process is
heedlessly going into overdrive in the current Congress.) |
|
And always, the administrative requirements - and administrative costs - of an ever-more-complicated system of administered alternatives to market cost constraints served instead to absorb vast percentages of health care resources and continued to impose unwelcome intrusions into patient-physician relationships.
Naturally, government, too, was not the answer as it inevitably responded to a wide array of political and bureaucratic imperatives. The wealthy could still procure the health care they wanted, but the broad middle class was being stripped by the rising costs of the third party payer system of many of the choices they might have otherwise had. |
E) The Social Engineering Agenda
Unlimited ambition:
& |
The authors' search for health care
system alternatives is limited to systems that support "the value of
social cohesion." The authors apparently do not believe that the health
care problem is complicated enough. & |
The authors view it as essential that the interests of inidividuals be sacrificed for the broader societal interest in a universal system. |
The system must also serve as a mechanism for social engineering
- for achieving egalitarian outcomes. They dread the prospect that government
may ultimately resort to a voucher system - that it might even resort to one "that is income
related" - in response to Medicare cost problems. "That, of course,
would end social insurance Medicare as we know it." (Horrors!) The voucher
alternative is mentioned just once. |
Inevitably, choices have to be made. Public health budgets now
leave many desirable activities under-funded. There is an observable decline in
the public health infrastructure - a particularly grave defect in the event of a
major terrorist attack. Not satisfied that the problem in the U.S. is difficult
enough to challenge government capabilities, the authors also believe the U.S.
should be funding research into tropical diseases that the affected undeveloped
nations cannot fund.
|
|
There is simply not enough in the public health budget to achieve all these desirable objectives. |
Medical education, too, suffers from the varied noxious impacts
of the third party payer mass medicine system. Of course, medical education has
been considered to be 'in crisis" throughout the 20th century, yet seems to
have managed quite well. As always, the primary need seems to be more funding. |
Then, the authors provide this remarkable sentence about the current health care system mess:
|
|
Individual physicians remain too preoccupied with the demands of their practices to get actively involved in broader policy issues, so the AMA decline has left the profession without an effective voice in the policy debates. |
Useful coverage of medical care distributional problems is
provided by the authors. They cover issues related to rapidly rising malpractice
premiums, the financing of services for the uninsured, simplification of third
party payer administrative procedures, the increasing emphasis on preventive
services, the need to increase the funding for public health care
infrastructure, and the declining membership of the AMA. Individual physicians
remain too preoccupied with the demands of their practices to get actively
involved in broader policy issues, so the AMA decline has left the profession
without an effective voice in the policy debates. |
Then, once again, the authors' ignorance of basic economics is exhibited. With the failure of Hillary care, they assert, "the nation chose -- or was forced to -- rely on free-market competition as the solution to the various health issues," including the uninsured, misdistribution of resources, and rapidly rising costs. "To the nation's regret, the free market failed to provide the needed remedies." (emphasis added)
The authors are well aware of the differences between the current system and a functioning free market system, but choose to view those differences as market failure rather than as failures of the administered alternatives (the third party payer mechanisms, the vast administered pricing segment, the managed care mechanisms, and the welfare programs that together dominate the system). |
The uninsured:
& |
The estimate of the uninsured is approximately 45
million. The authors estimate that 60% of the uninsured between 18 and 65
are employed, and 25% work for large firms or are their dependents but many are
part time employees without insurance benefits. Actually, only 10% of non-Hispanic
whites are uninsured. Immigrants and minorities are more likely to be uninsured. & |
The uninsured receive health care through emergency rooms and other ad hoc arrangements. This is spasmodic, ineffective and expensive. Their health outcomes are considerably worse than for those with insurance. The current method is so expensive, that the authors estimate that insuring the uninsured would increase national health spending by just 3% - or about $40.7 billion.
As it is, health care for the uninsured poor is paid for - through taxes and through "cost shifting" - charges passed on to the insured as overhead and covered by their premiums. It constitutes a sales tax that punishes those that purchase insurance.
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2007 Dan Blatt