BOOK REVIEW
China's Economic Transformation
by
Gregory C. Chow
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 4, No. 7, 7/1/02.
Economic conditions in China:
& |
China's economic transformation from a
communist centrally planned economy to a bureaucratic market economy is clearly
analyzed and explained by Princeton Prof. Gregory C. Chow. Decades of experience working in
China and advising Chinese government officials have provided the author with a broad
practical understanding of Chinese society and its economy. This enables him to provide
convincing explanations of the current state of the Chinese economy - how it got
to its current status - its strengths and weaknesses - and its prospects. & |
This is a textbook. In about 400 pages, it analyzes history and applies traditional
economic analysis and mathematical econometrics in analyzing and
explaining the Chinese economy. There are in fact many pages of econometric
analysis.
On the other hand, this is an excellent - perhaps
essential - text for any course on modern China. |
Chow successfully provides "a clear picture of the dynamic and continuing process of transformation from a planned economy to a market economy."
Government economic planning was recognized as a disaster, and there was widespread disgust among the people and also within the government.
Commitment and skill at the top, ample human capital among the Chinese people, and the exuberant popular response to economic freedom are factors that Chow believes assure continued rapid economic growth, albeit at a somewhat declining rate. |
Chow sets out to describe "the process of
economic transformation in China in its various aspects." He begins with
the historical-institutional background as a basis for subsequent economic
analysis. In this way, he successfully provides
"a clear picture of the dynamic and continuing process of transformation
from a planned economy to a market economy."
As an autocratic socialist political system, China lacked
the economic institutions and governance systems essential for functioning
market systems. There was no pertinent political know how. There was no recent
history of trial and error with policies designed to facilitate market commerce.
The political process was soon guided and driven by pragmatic market
forces loosed by economic liberalization. Grass roots private and village and
township enterprises quickly took on institutional lives of their own.
Commitment and skill at the top, ample human capital among the Chinese people,
and the exuberant popular response to economic freedom are factors that Chow
believes assure continued rapid economic growth, albeit at a somewhat declining
rate. |
Economic wealth has spread, giving the Chinese people "much more political power than before." Foreign trade and investment have opened contacts with the outside world. Modern concepts of law and democracy are becoming increasingly familiar. Significant legal reforms have been initiated. |
Chinese historical and cultural traditions heavily impact the
transformation process. Social networking - "guanxi" - permeates
commercial arrangements. Bureaucratic traditions - both predating and since
Communist rule - still powerfully influence government officials, state owned
enterprises ("SOEs"), and banking and financial systems, and even
private enterprises. Political and cultural constraints remain
powerful under a political system that remains autocratic.
|
There is an earnest desire within the Party to improve conditions and strengthen China. |
China skeptics have been proven wrong on many fronts, Chow
notes. Leadership power struggles have been suitably contained within the
Party's political system. Hong Kong has been largely permitted to continue under
its separate system. Recent economic crises in Asia have not forced a
devaluation of the Chinese yuan. |
The Chinese people are hard working and entrepreneurial. (Indeed, like expatriates from India, Chinese have prospered everywhere but in their native land.) The Chinese bureaucracy in various ways both supports and hinders transformation. Traditional business practices that are heavily dependent on family and social contacts hinder foreign investment and the needed modernization of the legal system. Traditions still favor socialistic collective values over individual freedom. As a result both of humiliations in their recent history and pride in their longer history, nationalism is strong.
Indeed, Chow affirms that: "Power corrupts, and absolute power corrupts absolutely." |
Reasons for skepticism:
Neither the debt nor the equity sides of the financing mechanism are functioning well enough to provide the financing needed for widespread reorganization. The major banks are mired in politically directed non performing loans that continue to increase - corporate governance does not inspire confidence in equities - and the government's finances are increasingly burdened with deficits and formal and informal guarantees.
Boosting - or even maintaining - agricultural incomes without moving most of China's many hundreds of millions of farmers off the land so farm size can be increased is simply not possible since there are no alternative sources of employment available for them. |
|
The politicized collectivist management and conglomerate structure of the township and village enterprises is neither efficient nor flexible enough to respond effectively to rapidly shifting competitive pressures. |
|
Another impossibility is the allocation of appropriate incentives to state enterprise managers to induce efficiency, appropriate expansion of capacity, and effective development of new products.
The planning process became subject to delays, frequent revisions, and a lack of reality. |
Without profits and market wages and salaries, another
impossibility is the allocation of appropriate incentives to state enterprise
managers to induce efficiency, appropriate expansion of capacity, and effective
development of new products. "However, it is difficult for the planning
authority to judge which enterprise managers should be rewarded when the
production targets are set arbitrarily and the economic conditions of the
enterprise cannot be ascertained accurately." |
Communist party committees existed at all levels of each enterprise, leaving vague the division of authority and responsibility between management and Party committees. |
SOEs had a dual management
system. Communist party committees existed at all levels of each enterprise,
leaving vague the division of authority and responsibility between management
and Party committees. "Interference by party members in administrative
matters is a serious problem in Chinese industry, especially when members do not
have the required educational background or administrative experience to play a
leadership role." (They also bear no personal financial responsibility for
the impact of their actions.) |
An incentive problem arises because the farmer is not paid according to the marginal product of his labor.
For industry, the lack of incentives was joined by widespread mismatches of jobs and workers and inputs.
The labor bureau staff will often assign the more desirable jobs as compensation for favors.
Industrial planning was plagued by perverse incentives.
|
Standard economic theory is applicable to the Chinese Communist experience, Chow emphasizes.
|
Political organization:
& |
China has 21 provinces, 5 autonomous
regions, and 3 major municipalities. These contain prefectures and large cities.
Prefectures contain counties and small cities. The 53,000 communes were under
the 2,000 counties. The cities are divided into neighborhoods, streets and
courtyards. Factories were frequently controlled at the county or city level,
while neighborhoods exercised control over small business units. The ministries
and provincial governments directly control some major industrial enterprises. & |
Further confusion was created by the powerful committees of the Communist Party which ran parallel to government agency organization from the State Council right down to the factory floor and commune. |
The State Council heads the executive branch of the government.
It had 40
ministries and bureaus controlling various economic functions. Coordination was
under the State Planning Commission, while evaluation was under the Economic
Commission. |
The central planning authority:
There is no incentive and no mechanism to transfer the excess material from one enterprise to another. |
Lacking market mechanisms and profit incentives, the central planning authority faced an impossible task in balancing material resources throughout the economy.
|
The planning authority frequently failed to understand the economic constraints limiting its choices. "Grossly unrealistic economic plans that cannot be implemented is not unusual." Perverse incentives permeate this massive bureaucracy at all levels. The self interest of lower level economic administrators frequently doesn't coincide with those of the national authority, creating serious problems. |
Since politics took precedence over economics, the planning
process was periodically disrupted by political storms. The supply ministry had
specialized material supply corporations and stations, processing factories and
service teams within each province and autonomous region. There were periodic
shifts in organization in efforts to improve matters, but the ministry was
smashed during the Cultural Revolution.
|
Since 1980, central planning has been reduced to the setting of targets for guidance, and a substantial consolidation and reduction has been achieved in the planning bureaucracy. |
Substantial levels of local administrative power have persisted throughout Chinese
history, and the administrative units of different provinces frequently have
objectives at odds with those of the central planning authority. Thus, some flexibility did persist.
The central control apparatus
was never total. Local authorities had varying degrees of discretion to
influence operations. They could frequently solve their own production and
distribution problems through barter and other arrangements. Before the Cultural
Revolution, some price flexibility was also permitted, which also facilitated
operations. |
Township and village collectives:
As with private farming, the township and village collectives were an unexpected advantage of the early reforms. |
Urban and rural collectives grew
explosively after 1978, substantially exceeding state owned enterprise
("SOE") production by the 1990s. As with private farming, they
were not initially a part of the reform plans of the central
government. They were an unexpected advantage of the economic freedom
provided by the early reforms. & They arose because local government needed the revenue of these enterprises and also needed to employ the rural labor that became excess as private farming increased agricultural productivity. Local governments were initially the only source of capital, buildings, and political and financial connections. Local government also offered managerial talent, and the influence of local political leaders provided a substitute for nonexistent legal rights. & |
These collectives are financially accountable. They are intended to
earn a profit and must operate under firm budget constraints. They can hire and
fire workers and pay market wages and salaries, and are subject to competition
from other producers. |
State owned enterprises ("SOEs"): |
Reform of the SOEs turned
out to be far more difficult and far less successful. These reform efforts have
continued for two decades. & |
Autonomy, some reliance on market pricing, competition and profit retention were simply not enough. There remained a lack of managerial know-how and appropriate managerial incentives.
"The appropriate link between marginal profits and the manager's marginal benefits remains a serious problem in enterprise reform in China."
The managers are still underpaid. They were bureaucrats appointed by a board of directors which consisted of the same government and Party officials as before. The government board had neither incentives nor ability to monitor the behavior of the enterprise managers.
|
First, in 1984, SOEs were given some autonomy with regard to
production, supply, marketing, pricing, investment, and personnel..
Thus, the initial 1984 reforms were both revolutionary and limited in
scope, "because it was not possible to go further." But by 1987, the "contract responsibility system" was introduced.
|
Rapid reform of SOEs would pose significant unemployment problems. |
Nevertheless, some significant increases in total factor productivity
and operational efficiency are observable as a result of the reform effort.
Moreover, for smaller and medium sized SOEs transformed into employee owned
corporations, results were better. They behaved more like similar enterprises in
less developed capitalist market economies due to similar management, worker
compensation and other incentives. |
Private enterprise:
& |
Individual owned and overseas funded enterprises
have also achieved significant proportions, so that SOE production - although
also expanding - has nevertheless shrunk proportionately from over
three quarters of gross industrial output to about one quarter. |
Foreign investment: |
"Exploitation"
propaganda against foreign investment has been partially rejected by China. It has set up special
economic zones and opened up 14 cities to encourage and reap the benefits of
foreign investment. & |
As a result, modern managerial systems and business practices have been introduced, and a legal framework for conducting business transactions has been developed. China thus also reaps the many rewards of heightened competition in domestic markets.
Nevertheless, many Chinese officials remain antagonistic to market mechanisms, and restraints and interferences of various kinds will remain.
There is no western style legal system, and the Chinese have their own habits, ethics, outlooks and training. The economic power is in the hands of the bureaucrats, and they are looking to make money from their positions. It is thus essential to find the right people for bureaucratic approvals and as partners.
If Chinese partners can learn your technology, they can set up competing businesses without you. |
China thus gets capital, new technology, and managerial and labor
skills. As a result, modern managerial systems and business practices have been
introduced, and a legal framework for conducting business transactions has been
developed. China thus also reaps the many rewards of heightened competition in
domestic markets.
It is expected that much of this will improve under WTO membership.
|
Foreign trade:
& |
Foreign trade constituted about one third of GDP in
1998. Chow considers China an open economy. Advantaged by abundant cheap
labor, exports of such items as textiles, clothing, shoes, toys, sports goods
and tools go almost entirely to the developed world. China imports capital
intensive goods such as autos and computers. Rapidly increasing hard currency
reserves, and a desire to join such international agencies as the WTO and APEC,
are among the driving forces behind trade liberalization. & |
Once resources are not priced by the competitive forces of demand and supply, it is difficult for any planner to make economically correct decisions concerning what to produce, how much to produce, and what and how much to export and import, not to speak of the need to provide proper incentives to the economic agents to carry out their tasks.
With free trade and market rates for foreign exchange, there can not be a shortage of foreign exchange.
|
Initial efforts at foreign exchange controls achieved predictably poor results. During the 1990s, foreign exchange rates were instead set close to the Hong Kong market rate of 8.3 yuan to the dollar. Chow explains the difficulties and inefficiencies involved in China's early efforts at exchange rate and foreign trade controls. He compares this with the ease and benefits of Hong Kong's free trade, low tax policy.
The author explains the limitations and inevitable failures of protectionist industrial planning measures. Whether protecting "infant industries" or "declining industries," protectionist measures may favor some owners and workers, "but they are bad in general for the consumers of the countries concerned."
With free trade and market rates for foreign exchange, there can not be a shortage of foreign exchange.
Currency stability was
maintained during the Asian financial crisis due to China's low inflation rate,
a substantial trade surplus, and inflows of foreign direct investment. These
factors continue. |
Trade liberalization: |
China has decided to remove many of its
trade restraints in several stages to avoid sudden disruptions when meeting
its WTO membership requirements
pursuant to its agreements. & |
The reduction of trade and investment restraints will be gradual, and the central, provincial and local governments retain many regulatory powers with which they can hinder foreign competition. There is as yet no great rush of foreign interests to push their way into the Chinese market. |
WTO membership and consequent reductions in trade restraints
during the next five years are expected to benefit Chinese consumers by
increasing quality and reducing prices of goods and services. Competition will
force Chinese producers to lower prices and improve quality. However, many may
not be able to adjust sufficiently to survive.
|
Education and the legal system: |
Great strides have been made in
opening up education. Foreign lecturers and textbooks and opportunities to
study abroad proliferate. & |
Regard for the law and courts is low. The result of decades of Communist rule has been a widespread acceptance of illegal activity - something that was often essential for survival under Communism. |
Development of a modern legal system is also being
attempted - but with considerably less success. A wide array of financial and
commercial laws have been passed. The judicial system has been expanded, and
lawyers have been trained, and the courts are deciding more cases - including
suits against the government.
|
The Taiwan model:
Essentially, freedom and economic opportunities, however incomplete, succeeded in developing the Chinese economy. |
Interestingly, much of this reform effort was copied from the
successful earlier Taiwanese example. "Essentially, by giving freedom and
economic opportunities, however incomplete, to the Chinese people, the
government of both regions of China succeeded in developing the Chinese
economy." The promotion of exports was similar to the earlier Taiwanese
approach, as was the emphasis on price stability, the lifting of import
restrictions, and the setting of monetary exchange rates close to market rates
while maintaining monetary discipline. |
Interim results of reform:
The Chinese people have greeted economic freedom enthusiastically, and used it with entrepreneurial and managerial skill - just as they have done outside China for many decades. |
The reform effort has proceeded gradually through pragmatic pursuit of experimental policies. Success has depended crucially on the determined reforming emphasis of China's top leadership since 1978. The exact statistics have been questioned, but the visible results are indisputable.
It should also be noted that the Chinese people have greeted economic
freedom enthusiastically, and used it with entrepreneurial and managerial
skill - just as they have done outside China for many decades. Success has
supported further reform. Thousands of overseas Chinese have also contributed
financial capital and know how. Today, about three quarters of the Chinese
economy is market driven. |
Problems with the bureaucratic market economy: |
The continued
influence of the Communist Party and the government bureaucracy "limits
the extent to which free enterprise can flourish in China." However, with
the economy improving and Chinese prestige rising, the government is widely
popular and unlikely to undergo substantial changes. & |
Bureaucratic approvals absorb money, effort and time. The scope of an enterprise can be restricted, both as to activities and size permitted. It is still impossible for a private enterprise to grow large. |
Corruption and other means of acquiring economic rents continue despite preventive efforts and the occasional execution of offenders. Bureaucratic approvals absorb money, effort and time. The scope of an enterprise can be restricted, both as to activities and size permitted. It is still impossible for a private enterprise to grow large. This is what Chow accurately describes as a "bureaucratic market economy."
|
Assets under government care deteriorate over time.
Rent seeking is a natural substitute in socialist systems for the profit motive.
Where money bribes are dangerous or inconvenient, "guanxi" - relationships of mutual favors - proliferate.
Without income incentives for effort, labor productivity was everywhere low and the quality of services was everywhere poor.
"The people are humiliated continuously by bureaucrats who control assets yielding services necessary for daily living." |
The misuse of labor, physical assets, and human capital under the Chinese bureaucratic market system, and the perverse incentives of socialist systems, are analyzed by Chow.
|
"Corruption is still prevalent and the end of it is not in sight." |
Even after reforms, state control over economic resources
remains high. Socialist controls over economic assets - including controls over
human beings - and restrictions on their use impose a variety of negative
effects on productive activities. |
Problems with SOEs:
& |
Major government monopolies remain -
especially in international trade and in the distribution of agricultural commodities.
The government intends to keep ownership and
control of certain major industries. The SOEs always receive favored treatment.
However, the government will encourage flexibility, better
management and downsizing. Social safety net programs are intended to
cushion the employment blow. & |
The system does not provide SOE management with appropriate incentives. Management is generally of low quality and self interested. Their pay is considerably less than in the other sectors of the economy, and the SOEs lack suitable governance systems. |
Although improvements have in fact been made, the SOEs remain a problem. Several social entitlements interfere with reform efforts. SOEs provide not just jobs and wages, but pensions, housing, education and health care.
Reality confirms theory. The system does not provide SOE management with appropriate incentives to work for the benefit of the enterprise. Management is generally of low quality and self interested, weaknesses that were "magnified under the institution of central planning." Their pay is considerably less than in the other sectors of the economy, and the SOEs lack suitable governance systems. Competition has forced some productivity improvements, but both physical and human capital remains very outdated.
|
"Since the marginal benefit of producing extra output belongs to the farm household, there are great incentives to produce."
In small enterprises, where managers paid a rent and kept the profits, they quickly began to pay higher wages to their most productive workers, and output quickly soared. In SOEs, where practical, shifts to piecework pay or to "leasing" arrangements resulted in rapid increases in production. |
The "Responsibility System" was started at the beginning of the reform effort when farmers were given the right to farm
land distributed to them in return for meeting a product delivery quota. The
effect was the same as in a market economy where farmers work leased land and
can keep all the profit after paying rent and other expenses. "Since the
marginal benefit of producing extra output belongs to the farm household, there
are great incentives to produce."
|
Proper supervision of management performance remains impossible for lack of objective standards of success. Since cognizant government officials don't risk their own funds in the SOEs, there is no incentive to find capable managers.
Appointments are made on the basis of political influence. There is no penalty for these officials if SOE shares suffer low p/e ratios. Failure is routinely overcome with subsidies. |
Restructured SOEs under the responsibility system still suffer from majority government ownership and government appointment of managers and directors. Proper supervision of management performance remains impossible for lack of objective standards of success. Since cognizant government officials don't risk their own funds in the SOEs, there is no incentive to find capable managers. Appointments are made on the basis of political influence. There is no penalty for these officials if SOE shares suffer low p/e ratios. Failure is routinely overcome with subsidies.
A variety of ownership reforms are underway. For some SOEs, shares
were sold to workers and managers, but transfers of those shares were permitted
only between those shareholders. For other SOEs, transfers are permitted to the
general public, and some have their shares traded on Chinese and even
international stock exchanges. Central and provincial governments retain
controlling interests in many SOEs, but some were sold to overseas Chinese and
other foreign owners. |
Problems with banks: There is still political pressure and economic temptation to extend credit at higher risk than benefit-cost calculations justify. |
Banking law has been considerably reformed, but actual practices remain governed by political and bureaucratic considerations.
|
The bad loan problem has not yet gotten out of hand in relation to the financial resources of the government, which is expected to support the system in any crisis. |
The large state owned
commercial banks hold about 70% of China's banking assets. They are subjected to credit quotas. About 80% of the loans of the four large state banks are to SOEs - and
between 20% and 25% - about $200 billion - are non performing. Nevertheless, the
operations still appear to be profitable. They must pay a 33% tax on income
and an 8% turnover tax on gross revenue. |
Poor customer service, corruption, misuse of bank funds for illegitimate purposes or the purposes of bank managers all still exist, although improvements have been and continue to be made. |
The central bank - the "People's Bank" - remains a political executive arm of the central government and lacks independence. In addition to the ordinary activities of central banks, it engages in the allocation of credit in favor of politically favored sectors like the SOEs, and controls interest rates. High rates on certain time deposits and low rates on loans "have forced commercial banks to find risky and possibly illegal outlets for their funds." Bank reserve requirements have been set too low, making it difficult to avoid periodic surges in the money supply and resulting surges in price inflation.
The large state-owned commercial banks still lack managerial
expertise. "Incentive problems for management and staff, inability to
discharge workers, and bureaucratic behavior among the staff are all
present." Poor customer service, corruption, misuse of bank funds for
illegitimate purposes or the purposes of bank managers all still exist, although
improvements have been and continue to be made. |
The Chinese government remains slow in allowing "nonstate financial institutions" to flourish. It remains difficult to start a nonstate commercial bank. |
China now also has many rural and urban credit cooperatives, foreign
banks and banks from Hong Kong and Taiwan, as well as small
commercial banks. The banking system
still has many problems, but appears to be functioning and slowly improving. |
Population:
Population is still growing at about 1 % per year - but this rate is expected to decline further. |
Two thirds of China's 1 1/4 billion people are still
rural. Population is still growing at about 1% per year - a bit faster than in
the U.S. However, as the population becomes increasingly urbanized and as
economic development proceeds, population growth should decline further. & Chow shows that these two forces - rather than the government's population policies - account for the vast majority of the decline in population growth. While the "one couple, one child" policy in 1980 had a dramatic impact on the ratio of male-to-female children in some rural provinces, and some parents drowned female babies, the statistical impact for the nation as a whole was insignificant. Since 1983, the one child policy has been relaxed in rural areas if the first child is a girl. & |
The author points out that the population density in China is less than in
most European nations. Indeed, most provinces have relatively low population
densities, and it is the highest density provinces that enjoy the highest per
capita income. Today, China exports more food than it imports. |
The central and western provinces:
& |
The central and western parts of China, containing two
thirds of China's land area and over one quarter billion people, will receive
increasing attention now that China has the resources to promote their
development. These areas suffer from inconvenient location, lack of adequate
transportation and other infrastructure, lack of legal and educational
institutions, and brain drain as their most talented people are drawn to the
more prosperous east. However, these areas are rich in natural resources and
land. & |
The government's role involves infrastructure construction,
environmental protection, a shift from heavy industry to consumer goods
industries, economic reforms, and the promotion of educational, scientific and
technological institutions. The infrastructure needs are massive.
Transportation, power and water projects along with the development of human
capital "will make the economic environment in the west more attractive for
domestic and foreign investment," and facilitate market directed commerce.
Chinese agriculture still has much room for productivity growth. |
|
Environmental problems:
& |
China has accumulated massive pollution
problems that are only beginning to be addressed. (The massive disregard for
environmental concerns under Chairman Mao was very similar to that under Soviet
Russia and in a wide variety of other socialist states.) Nine of the world's
ten most polluted cities are in China. China has many laudable environmental
laws, but like all laws in China, they are poorly enforced. |
Analyses of economic and political prospects: |
In working with his economic growth model for
China, Chow evaluates the reliability of the Chinese economic statistics.
Conceding that there has been widespread falsification in the past, he asserts
that there has been considerable improvement in recent years, and that the data
are now accurate enough for econometric purposes such as measuring average rates
of change over time. Evaluating the results of prior studies, he concludes that
they "show reasonable results when judged by economic theory and related
empirical studies." & |
The model draws attention to such variables as changes in labor force growth or productivity. Government policy reforms and WTO membership may alter investment rates and thus productivity, the evaluation of which can be facilitated by an econometric model. |
The model is also dependent on "normal" overall conditions.
Chow eliminates as abnormal the years from the start of the Great Leap Forward through the
first years of the Cultural Revolution - 1958 through 1969.
Chow concedes that his forecast for substantial but slightly slower growth could have been just as easily reached without econometric analysis, simply by assuming a slightly slower growth rate and drawing a simple graph. However, the model draws attention to such variables as changes in labor force growth or productivity. Government policy reforms and WTO membership may alter investment rates and thus productivity, the evaluation of which can be facilitated by an econometric model. "Without a model the effects of these changes, and of government policy, cannot be taken into account in a forecast." |
|
|
"It is the sound judgment and knowledge of the forecaster that determine the accuracy of a forecast," whether or not dependent on an econometric analysis.
"Even in the use of econometric models for forecasting, judgment plays an important role." |
Chow candidly acknowledges many of the limitations of econometrics.
He wisely refuses to confine his analytical efforts to
econometric analysis. "It is counterproductive to confine economics to the use of
quantitative methods only by giving up other means of acquiring knowledge."
|
Neither the computer nor mathematics have "yet surpassed the human brain" for analyzing such factors. |
"Econometrics is a special case when the variables can be
conveniently measured and when the effects can be formulated in
mathematical equations," Chow perceptively points out. He cites
human capital and political intentions as vital variables that must be
omitted, since they are impossible to measure. "Any measurements
constructed are likely to be so arbitrary as not to be able to yield
better predictions than the use of common sense and intuition." & It may also be impossible to "specify a set of predictive mathematical relations that would give correct weights to different factors that interact in a complicated way." Neither the computer nor mathematics have "yet surpassed the human brain" for analyzing such factors. & |
If the political situation is as stable and
economically progressive as Chow presents it, he has every reason to be
optimistic about China's economic future. His analysis is based on a variety of assumptions that appear quite
reasonable. A key variable is the slow but impressively determined economic
reform efforts of the past two decades. |
Chow notes that "there is no need to have 'perfect' institutions to grow rapidly, as long as important market incentives are permitted to operate in important parts of the economy."
China will enjoy growth rates initially at about 7.5% declining to about 6.5% until 2020. Indeed, even with modestly declining rates of growth, China's real GDP may well catch up to that of the U.S. by 2020. |
Chow ultimately makes a very convincing economic forecast based
on his analysis of economic fundamentals - without econometric equations. The
existence of market institutions and high quality human capital will drive
further economic growth. His positive estimations of the capabilities of China's
top leaders, the ability of the Party machinery to continue to bring capable
leaders forward and resolve transition problems, and the widespread contentment
of the Chinese people with their current economic progress fortifies this
optimism.
|
The Chinese economy will become more modern, with private and service sectors increasing as a percent of GDP, and the SOEs and agriculture continuing to grow but declining as a percent of GDP. |
Prospects for broader progress towards modernity are also
evaluated. Chow expects continued development of China's legal system -
further increases in autonomy of the National People's Congress as it grapples
with complex modern legislative tasks - continued improvements in information
flows - further development of modern management know how - and the rise to
power over time of better educated and informed political leaders. |
Keynesian analysis: |
Chow applies standard Keynesian theory - with subsequent modifications in such factors as income and investment and the addition of dynamic factors - to analyze short term - business cycle - fluctuations in the Chinese economy. He presents this analysis as is expected of today's textbook writers. However, to his credit, he does not assume validity. |
It does make a difference whether you build pyramids or roads - and whether those roads connect markets or royal palaces.
Business mismanagement and the cumulating impacts of government economic policy blunders play no role in econometric analyses.
Keynesian remedies for the business cycle are just palliatives that fail to address fundamental problems.
No model of capitalist economic systems can be valid if it fails to highlight the roles profits. |
|
Indeed, Chow perceptively acknowledges that this analysis is dependent on the validity of the underlying Keynesian theory - and wisely specifically leaves that question open. Wisely, he does not rely on econometrics for his analytical conclusions, so these econometric segments can be simply ignored without loss. Later in the book, he candidly concedes that:
But here, Chow himself gives credence to a
common theoretical fallacy - that there is a tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment. (Except in the short run, inflation above de minimus levels
always causes unemployment and undermines economic stability.) |
Monetary analysis:
& |
The relationship between China's monetary factors and price inflation, however, are much more appropriate subjects for mathematical reasoning due to the availability of monetary and pricing data. Although far from perfect, this data is sufficiently reliable for the purpose.
The author also provides interesting
analyses of the Chinese markets for housing and computers. |
The costs of Mao's policies:
& |
Chow uses econometric techniques to evaluate the long term damage caused by the two great economic disruptions initiated by Chairman Mao. The Great Leap Forward was far more disruptive than the Cultural Revolution. By one calculation, output and consumption would have been 2.7 times greater in 1992 but for these events. With more conservative methods, the figure falls to between 1.2 and 1.7 times greater.
|
About all the modest increase in per capita consumption prior to 1978 was due to the increase in labor participation rates, as women were brought into the labor force. This undoubtedly reduced the "nonmarket consumer goods and services" provided by housewives |
The author uses simulated growth rates - against which he compares the observed growth rates to estimate the long term losses caused by the two disruptions. It is revealing that his simulated growth rates are practically the same both before and after 1978.
Chow, of course, recognizes that the economic expansion prior to 1978
suffered from "distortions" as a result of the planned
industrialization and the insufficient emphasis on consumer goods and
consumption. He points out that about all the modest increase in per
capita consumption prior to 1978 was due to the increase in labor participation
rates, as women were brought into the labor force. This undoubtedly reduced the
"nonmarket consumer goods and services" provided by housewives
(something else that no econometric model can accurately include).
|
Governance:
& |
Some very costly ideological experiments around the
world have proven the superiority of free market mechanisms over central
planning, the author notes. However, government nevertheless does have many vital
roles to play. Among the most important is "to adopt institutional changes
which allow market forces to operate for the benefit of the economy." (As
FUTURECASTS puts it - to establish good governance that facilitates profit driven
market directed commerce.) & |
The appropriate government role includes monetary and budgetary
discipline, and limiting the impact of inevitable business cycle reverses. It
includes major
infrastructure projects - especially those involving monopoly services and/or
benefits that are difficult to allocate. These include highways, railroads,
power plants, water conservancy and flood control projects, environmental
protection facilities, and communications networks. Nevertheless, he notes that
some of this is being built by private entrepreneurs. |
"Industrial policy" is also discussed by
the author without
drawing any broad conclusions. He views favorably government assistance for
research and development. (Land grant agricultural colleges are long standing examples in
the U.S.) He provides examples in China and Taiwan. & He concludes that success is more likely when the government assists in technological development and avoids picking winners and losers. For developing nations, the author views government assistance as very beneficial because of the limitations of private capital and know-how. (That's why its important to provide an attractive environment for foreign investment - which invariably works far better than government assistance.) & |
|
Human capital and political stability are also among the
prerequisites for economic development. Chow correctly points out that market
incentives alone are not enough.
|
However, with respect to the essential benefits of property rights and private ownership, Chow exhibits a surprising lack of appreciation. He insists that different ownership and legal systems can be sufficient for economic development. (While this is certainly true within limits, it is certainly not true to the extent that Chow intends it.) Chow contends that: | |
|
|
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2002 Dan Blatt