BOOK REVIEW
Globalization And Its Discontents
by
Joseph E. Stiglitz
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 5, No. 4, 4/1/03.
A Keynesian critique of the IMF:
& |
It is important to be clear about what this book is
and is not. In "Globalization and its Discontents," Joseph E.
Stiglitz does not provide a critique of globalization. The book - written by a prominent economist who was the chief
economist and senior Vice President of the World Bank from 1997 to 2000 - is rather a
critique of the International Monetary Fund ("IMF") and other agencies
of international financial governance - principally the World Bank and the U.S.
Treasury. & |
Support for aggregate demand social spending is like foreign aid. It is government to government assistance through an international agency - delivered into the hands of political leaders frequently of proven incompetence and who are frequently substantially corrupt. |
However, it is not even a critique of IMF objectives
or most of its policies. Although there is some criticism of policy, the book
primarily criticizes the process by which
policies are implemented, the timing with which they are executed, and - most
important - the policy concerns that are omitted. Much of this criticism is
clearly well taken. |
Private sector imbalances such as speculative bubbles do have to be addressed - overextended financial and business entities do need to be restructured - and government corruption and incompetence cannot be ignored. |
But Stiglitz is no dinosaur Keynesian. The importance of getting the fundamentals right
are not ignored by the author. & He fully understands that developing nations need the systems of good governance essential for the proper functioning of profit driven, market directed commerce - and they need the political institutions that support the development and functioning of an empowered civil society. While he advocates committing large sums to avoid recessions and unemployment in developing nations facing various financial crises, he is aware that private sector imbalances such as speculative bubbles do have to be somehow addressed - that overextended financial and business entities do need to be restructured - and that government corruption and incompetence cannot be ignored. & |
Where Stiglitz goes wrong is where you would expect a Keynesian to go wrong.
|
Problems with globalization: |
"Why has
globalization - a force that has brought so much good - become so
controversial?" Recognizing the widespread benefits of globalization from
the outset, Stiglitz nevertheless emphasizes the very real defects - and why
these defects hurt vast numbers of people, and generate protests and
opposition that could threaten to end globalization and all its benefits -
something that
occurred during the previous globalization period a century ago. |
"The Western countries have pushed poor countries to eliminate trade barriers, but kept up their own barriers, preventing developing countries from exporting their agricultural products and so depriving them of desperately needed export income."
"The loosening of capital market controls in Latin America and Asia" benefited Western banks but caused great harm in those regions when "hot money" flows flooded in and then out, leaving behind "collapsed currencies and weakened banking systems."
World Bank and other Western loans remain to be repaid even when the projects they financed fail. |
Despite globalization, poverty remains widespread and
deeply entrenched. Much of Africa plunges deeper into misery. Russia and other nations transitioning from communism to capitalism,
and nations in Asia and Latin America, continue to suffer widespread disappointments.
|
Stiglitz then provides a remarkable paragraph - attributing most of the problems of the modern world to the failures of globalization.
Stiglitz himself admits that "these problems are hardly new." It is only now - with globalization - that hopelessness has been replaced with aspirations that - in all too many cases - are not being met.
|
|
Under globalization, there is no international government with democratic institutions capable of regulating international finance, providing mechanisms for compromise and accommodation of conflicting interests, and providing social safety nets for the unfortunate and those temporarily discomfited by change - and labor mobility is limited. |
Current globalization is similar to the
geographic expansion of the U.S. economy in the 19th and early 20th century.
The author
properly notes such similarities as declining transportation and communication
costs, market expansion, capital flows free to go where they could best be used,
and goods and services free to be sold anywhere in an expanding market. |
The International Monetary Fund: |
Stiglitz concentrates
his criticism on the IMF and the World Bank - and particularly on the former
- although of course knowledgeable of the important roles played by many other international financial institutions. & |
The author prefers the policies emphasized by the World Bank during the long tenure of Robert McNamara.
The need to deal with corrupt and inept governing practices and policies is recognized by Stiglitz. But he concentrates on the need to throw in more money - more "liquidity" - to shield economic systems from the consequences. |
The IMF - established in 1944 - was intended by
John Maynard Keynes and his followers - who were influential in its development - as a means of pressuring nations to use Keynesian remedies to combat
recessions that might negatively impact trade partners - and to provide loans to
assist them to pump up aggregate demand and maintain full employment. (As is
clear from economic history, this role was never even remotely fulfilled.)
The change was induced by Ronald Reagan and Margaret
Thatcher who "preached free market ideology." Stiglitz is sharply
critical of this new approach. (If third world reversals were less noticeable
before 1980, that was solely because there were so few advances.)
|
Stiglitz does not ignore the importance of getting the governance policies right and dealing with the excesses in the private sector.
Stiglitz criticizes IMF and World Bank efforts to force market reforms on frequently unwilling and otherwise unready third world nations.
Stiglitz is particularly and correctly critical of the removal of restraints on short term "hot" capital flows in undeveloped nations that still lack any semblance of proper government oversight for such capital markets. |
The IMF should function as intended by Keynes, the author asserts. It should provide "liquidity" (it should lend money) to nations in financial crisis even before needed reforms are negotiated. However, to his credit, Stiglitz does not ignore the importance of getting the governance policies right and dealing with the excesses in the private sector.
Since 1980, the Reagan-Thatcher free market policies have failed to achieve hoped for results in many nations. Rather than examining the particular policy causes for those failures, Stiglitz criticizes IMF and World Bank efforts to force market reforms on frequently unwilling and otherwise unready third world nations. He is particularly and correctly critical of the removal of restraints on short term "hot" capital flows in undeveloped nations that still lack any semblance of proper government oversight for such capital markets.
|
The changes forced by sudden liberalization of trade can easily destabilize third world nations. |
But stabilization, privatization, and market liberalization are not enough for economic success. Stiglitz is undoubtedly correct when he states:
All advanced nations applied protectionist policies for some of their domestic industries during their development stages, Stiglitz correctly points out. Perfectly open trading systems have never proven themselves in a development context.
The author also correctly points out that the changes forced by sudden
liberalization of trade can easily destabilize third world nations. (These
nations typically lack the credit and other market facilities and
entrepreneurial talent needed to
flexibly respond to rapid changes.)
|
The IMF wields immense influence over a poor
nation's access to credit - not just from governments, but from private sources as well.
Donors, too, will not provide funds to a nation that is out of compliance with IMF
requirements. Even debt relief - a recent welcome policy reform - will be
withheld from nations that are not in compliance. |
|
The author views the current crisis in Argentina as an IMF failure - but doesn't explain how that crisis could have been avoided under that nation's dysfunctional budget processes.
Stiglitz perceptively does not attack the reforms themselves, but the pace and sequence with which they are imposed. |
The experience in Argentina is presented as a prime example. The author views the current crisis in Argentina as an IMF failure.
However, Stiglitz perceptively does
not attack the reforms themselves, but the pace and sequence with which they
are imposed. |
Policy reform conditions for financial assistance:
& |
When nations require assistance because of some financial crisis, the IMF enforces its requirements of "conditionality" by paying out its loans in installments - each one dependent on the achievement of scheduled policy reforms.
|
The IMF forces nations in financial crisis to surrender a variety of subsidies and welfare expenditures to qualify for assistance.
Financial market liberalization and eliminating trade barriers, monopolies, and tax distortions - "may enhance long-run growth, but the disturbances to the economy as it strives to adjust, may only deepen its downturn" in the short run.
"Good policies cannot be bought." |
The IMF forces nations in financial crisis to surrender a variety of subsidies and welfare expenditures to qualify for assistance. This Stiglitz blames on IMF policies rather than on the financial mismanagement that undermined the financial strength needed to maintain these programs. He correctly accuses the IMF of mission creep beyond its intellectual and political capabilities.
Other conditions typically imposed - such as financial market liberalization and eliminating trade barriers, monopolies, and tax distortions - "may enhance long-run growth, but the disturbances to the economy as it strives to adjust may only deepen its downturn" in the short run. Changing the charter of the nation's central bank to make it more independent of political pressure is another condition frequently imposed.
Stiglitz is certainly correct in stating: "Good policies cannot be bought." If other economic policies are bad - or if the conditional policies are poorly implemented - or if corruption or other weaknesses remain too prevalent - the IMF cannot succeed. (That's one reason why debt relief has been withheld in some otherwise appropriate instances.) |
Keynesian assistance to support social programs during the crisis period might have provided needed political stability and support. |
Some of the specific reasons why IMF efforts fail are provided by the author:
|
For the programs to be implemented in an effective and sustainable manner, there must be a commitment of the country behind the program, based on a broad consensus.
Conditionality can prevent governments from just taking the money and then not making the needed policy changes. Rigid timetables help force the pace of needed change.
But at other times, the IMF has failed - because the policies were not well suited to the country - or because they created hostility - leaving the country just as impoverished and even more deeply in debt. |
The IMF should consult more widely within countries and bring local authorities on board for any required policy initiatives, the author advises. Consultation and consensus building is essential. Lack of citizen participation and lack of transparency are basic causes for resentment. The IMF negotiates in secret. (Almost all international negotiations of contentious issues are in secret - and the need to make decisions rapidly in the face of a rapidly progressing crisis would inevitably limit the scope of any discussions.)
The World Bank has been following this model - using the carrot of additional funds for those nations that use funds well - rather than the stick of imposed conditions. Nevertheless, the Bank remains in actual control because it controls the funds. There are those who resent even this retention of the power of the purse.
The IMF has in fact had some successes, the author
readily acknowledges. These occur when it is dealing with nations with good
economic policies already in place - or with nations capable of implementing
required reforms - or when involved with nations where the debate could be
shifted in ways favorable toward good economic policies. He recognizes that
conditionality can
prevent governments from just taking the money and then not making the needed
policy changes. Rigid timetables help force the pace of needed change.
|
IMF and World Bank management is chosen by the major developed nations without regard to experience in the third world.
International government institutions - just like national ones - are influenced by narrow vested interests.
|
The way the IMF and World Bank are governed is a focus of the author's criticism. Their management is chosen by the major developed nations without regard to experience in the third world. "The institutions are not representative of the nations they serve." He wants greater "openness and transparency." He expresses chagrin that international government institutions - just like national ones - are influenced by narrow vested interests.
Because of the narrow experience and concerns of the IMF, a country like Argentina "can get an 'A' grade even if it has double-digit unemployment for years, so long as its budget seems in balance and its inflation seems in control." (Argentina's complex of government budgets has not been even remotely in balance.)
|
Bail outs and moral hazard: |
Too much of the IMF's financial
assistance goes right out again to "bail out
the 'colonial power's' private sector creditors," Stiglitz notes. He
correctly blasts the IMF tendency to waste billions of dollars trying to
stabilize overvalued currencies. These vain efforts at stabilization force major
increases in interest rates that are especially disastrous for heavily indebted
economies. & |
The only beneficiaries of these wasteful IMF rescue efforts were those who were thus given time to bail out - frequently from recklessly created positions. |
An IMF rescue package provides time for banks to call in their loans. Money expended to support the currency exchange rate "temporarily at an unsustainable level" was largely wasted, leaving the stricken nations with an economy shocked by high interest rates, devalued currencies and a large obligation to repay to the IMF. The only beneficiaries of these wasteful IMF rescue efforts were those who were thus given time to bail out - frequently from recklessly created positions.
|
Ethiopia:
Aid flows to Ethiopia were actually more reliable than tax flows - which after all varied with economic conditions. |
The author refers to Ethiopia as another example. The IMF considered Ethiopia's budget insufficiently in balance
because it relied so heavily on aid for social expenditures like schools and
clinics. But these aid flows were actually more reliable than tax flows - which
after all varied with economic conditions.
|
The IMF also insisted on examining for approval individual financial transactions - like the sensible decision to prepay a high interest loan on an airplane.
The IMF also wanted to force Ethiopia to open up its tiny financial markets to Western competition, divide its largest bank into several pieces - that would then be too small to have any chance to compete - and stop administering interest rates so that they could be determined by market forces. This latter requirement would have ended the government policy of allocating cheap credit to its vast impoverished agricultural sector.
It was only with considerable effort that Stiglitz got
the World Bank to triple its lending to Ethiopia, and ultimately convinced IMF
officials of the error of their views with respect to poor countries that are
dependent on substantial flows of foreign aid. |
Botswana:
& |
Botswana was a development success story - although
it is presently being burdened by the AIDs epidemic. Botswana has enjoyed the
substantial benefits of its wealth in diamonds - something other African nations
have found to be more of a curse than a benefit. It sought and received advice
from economists who spent time studying its unique character, developed policies
that took the nation's social needs into account, and achieved substantial
growth rates for several decades. & |
IMF advice is essentially correct - it is just often terribly wrong with respect to sequence and pacing.
Conditions imposed as shock therapy in the midst of a crisis can tear a nation apart. |
However, this array of policies
included most of the things the IMF insists upon, the author points out. IMF advice is essentially
correct - it is just often terribly wrong with respect to sequence and pacing. When a drought
resulted in a financial crisis, there was little more the IMF could ask for.
Here, certainly, was a place for Keynesian policies - to help a well governed
nation get through a tough spot.
It's not that the basic IMF requirements are wrong,
Stiglitz notes. It's just that imposing them as shock therapy in the midst of a
crisis can tear a nation apart. (But, when can the IMF impose budgetary and
monetary discipline and good governance practices if not during a crisis when national political leaders can
no longer ignore their responsibilities?) |
The Washington consensus: |
Fiscal discipline,
privatization, and market liberalization - the basic elements of the
"Washington Consensus" - were the policies pushed during the 1980s and
1990s to deal with problems in Latin America, "and made considerable
sense." & |
Privatization: |
Stiglitz accepts the need for
privatization - governments generally make a mess of productive entities
that they run. However, he emphasizes that how government productive entities
are privatized - and the economic environment existing for privatized entities -
are vital factors often disregarded by the IMF and the World Bank. & |
How government productive entities are privatized - and the economic environment existing for privatized entities - are vital factors often disregarded by the IMF and the World Bank.
"Once a vested interest has been created, it has an incentive, and the money, to maintain its monopoly position, squelching regulation and competition, and distorting the political process along the way."
Economic growth involves governance practices far beyond mere privatization and budgetary and monetary discipline.
Privatization may not be a solution to government corruption - since a corrupt government will inevitably award its assets in a corrupt manner. |
Governments often have to do what is needed but
what the private market won't do. Social welfare programs and environmental
programs are prominent examples.
He also criticizes the initial loss of jobs, as private owners cut bloated labor forces to increase efficiency - often before the economy is functioning well enough to absorb these workers - causing widespread turmoil. "Privatization often destroys jobs rather than creating them."
The author dwells on the hardships of the resulting unemployment - never venturing a comparison with the hardships of the nonfunctional economic systems that would continue indefinitely without privatization. He correctly emphasizes that economic growth involves governance practices far beyond mere privatization and budgetary and monetary discipline.
The author correctly points out that privatization may
not be a solution to government corruption - since a corrupt government will
inevitably award its assets in a corrupt manner. "If government is corrupt,
there is little evidence that privatization will solve the problem." |
Russia is the prime example of corrupt privatization.
(See, "Transformation
economies and the Russian crisis," below.) & |
Trade: |
Trade liberalization, too,
can be pushed too far too fast. Here, too, the shock of market competition often
destroys jobs and businesses in an economy not yet flexible enough to rapidly
create new ones. Both entrepreneurship and access to financing may be widely
lacking. (This is generally especially true of access to equity financing.) & |
The "hypocrisy" of Western insistence on trade liberalization for Western exports while Western nations still impose restraints on the exports of undeveloped nations is properly blasted by Stiglitz. |
The "hypocrisy" of Western insistence
on trade liberalization for Western exports while Western nations still impose
restraints on the exports of undeveloped nations is properly blasted by Stiglitz.
Subsidies and tariff protection for agricultural products and textiles remain in
place. (Some welcome progress has been made in reducing textile restraints for
some third world producers, but the agricultural lobbies in the U.S. and Europe
and Japan are too powerful to be confronted.) |
Financial markets:
Capital market liberalization subjects immature financial systems to the temptations and risks of short term "hot money" borrowing - with disastrous results. |
Financial market liberalization "undertaken prematurely before strong financial institutions are in place," increases instability, Stiglitz correctly points out. Capital market liberalization subjects immature financial systems to the temptations and risks of short term "hot money" borrowing - with disastrous results. He notes that China was spared during the Asian contagion because of its "wise policies" in maintaining a controlled financial system.
|
Financial markets without proper regulation and policing will become subject to widespread abuses that market mechanisms by themselves cannot control, |
Financial markets without proper regulation and policing will become subject to widespread abuses that market mechanisms by themselves cannot control, Stiglitz properly emphasizes. A laissez faire approach to financial markets is doomed to failure.
|
Foreign investment:
"Temporary" protections designed to give local interests a chance to catch up and compete all too often become permanent, with permanent unnecessary costs for local consumers. |
The many advantages of foreign investment are recognized by Stiglitz, but he grieves for the local businesses, large and small, that crumble away in the face of foreign competition. Local ice cream manufacturers can't compete with Unilever's ice cream products. Local soft drink providers can't compete with Coca Cola and Pepsi. (Not always true!) However, he properly notes that "temporary" protections designed to give local interests a chance to catch up and compete all too often become permanent, with permanent unnecessary costs for local consumers.
|
Foreign investment in corruptly governed nations just benefits the corrupt ruling groups - and drives up the value of the currency - undermining the competitiveness of traditional exports. |
Some Asian nations that enjoy high savings rates - such
as China and Japan - have been able to develop rapidly without foreign
investment or with tightly controlled foreign investment. (This is not the
general rule among undeveloped nations, however.) |
Industrial policy: |
National
efforts at industrial policy are undermined by globalization. (Thank
goodness!) & |
Proper sequencing and pacing: |
"Market
fundamentalism" is properly criticized by Stiglitz for its simplistic
views of what is required for good governance that facilitates commerce. Fiscal
and monetary prudence is certainly an essential part of effective economic
policy. And, private property rights are certainly important. & |
Private property will not automatically generate the institutions and legal structures needed for realizing the full advantages of private property. |
However, laissez faire policies do not work in the real world of market imperfections and information limitations. And, private property will not automatically generate the institutions and legal structures needed for realizing the full advantages of private property.
|
Sequencing and pacing of reforms has been ignored by the IMF. Also ignored is the need to be "sensitive to the broader social context" of their programs.
|
|
Privatization must include policies that protect competition. Replacing government monopolies with private monopolies offers little or no benefits.
Replacing corrupt government administered systems with markets dominated by corrupt political influences or local Mafiosi achieves little.
Inattention to the pacing and sequencing of reforms "has resulted in job destruction outmatching job creation," and the exposure to market risks "outmatched the ability to create institutions for coping with risk, including effective safety nets."
|
The IMF is charged with an array of errors of
commission and omission.
The author summarizes his criticism:
|
Transformation economies and the Russian crisis: |
While Russians themselves must bear
most of the blame for their economic failures in their transformation to
capitalism, the "market fundamentalism" preached by Western advisers,
the U.S. Treasury, and the IMF, must also shoulder much of the blame. & |
Capitalism requires an environment that facilitates profit driven, market directed commerce - and that environment includes numerous factors of political governance and civic attitudes. |
IMF insistence on wasting billions of dollars in
vain efforts to defend Russia's overvalued currency here again caused considerable
damage for no benefit, facilitated capital flight, and played a major role in further undermining the
Russian economy. Ultimate devaluation in 1998 finally released the economy from
this burden and - with help from higher oil prices - facilitated recovery.
|
Poland is presented as a transformation nation with better sequencing and pace. Privatization was slower in Poland, which first concentrated on getting the supporting institutions right. These included "banks that actually lend, and a legal system that could enforce contracts and process bankruptcies fairly." While hyperinflation was rapidly addressed, eliminating the last modest levels of inflation took second place to concerns "such as the importance of democratic support for reforms, which entailed trying to keep unemployment low, providing benefits for those who were unemployed and adjusting pensions for inflation, and creating the institutional infrastructure required to make a market economy function."
|
|
Taiwan and China are examples of transition economies
that took a deliberate approach - not only redeploying resources from command
and control systems to market systems, but also steadily establishing more of
the institutions that underlie a market economy. (See, Chow, "China's
Economic Transformation.") They have thus had remarkable success.
"Rather than prolonged transition recession, they had close to double-digit
growth."
|
Above all, throughout all levels of government, Russia lacked the essential pervasive desire to facilitate the success of the transformation effort. Instead, corruption and incompetence undermined all efforts.
|
The experience in China and Taiwan was ignored by the "radical
reformer" advisers - who thought that market direction by itself would
propel the economic system in the most positive direction. However, Russia
lacked an appropriate legal and regulatory framework, private property rights, contracts and commercial
law and bankruptcy procedures, functional markets for equity and debt capital,
competition policies, modern banking institutions, and much more that is needed
to create an investment friendly environment. It lacked effective mechanisms for creditors
to collect debts and governments to collect taxes. Also lacking was stability in
the political environment - which is impossible unless the vast mass of the
population can see that they can achieve real improvements in their lives under
the new market system. |
Under these conditions, managers, controlling owners, and regional and municipal governments had no incentives for good governance. Instead, they got what they could by stripping assets and demanding the "rents" of corrupt practices.
The social institutions and empowered civil society that are needed to support the system didn't exist. |
Since legitimate enterprise was impossible under these conditions, managers, controlling owners, and regional and municipal governments had no incentives for good governance. Instead, they got what they could by stripping assets and demanding the "rents" of corrupt practices.
Markets for both inputs and outputs didn't exist. The social institutions and empowered civil society that are needed to support the system didn't exist. There was no safety net for the unemployed, no ability to obtain housing where the jobs existed.
|
The wealthy - including those made wealthy by political influence - care not for rule of law, property rights, a free press, and protection from monopolies. They have other ways of taking care of themselves - and do nothing to support either democracy or market economic systems. |
The IMF and the U.S. Treasury favored shock therapy.
However, actual events proved the superiority of the gradualist approach.
Stiglitz provides a blow-by-blow account of how the transformation effort
unraveled, and how the 1990s became a lost decade for Russia.
The author perceptively notes one of the most important casualties of this failure. The "social capital" that provides an environment of trust within which markets can most effectively function has been destroyed by widespread looting of Russia's assets. He offers several other insightful conclusions.
|
The Asian contagion: |
Stiglitz' account of the
"Asian miracle" is at odds with that of most others who have
studied it. He properly credits the role of high savings rates and stable
monetary and budgetary policies. However, he also praises the government command
economy practices in the region. & |
The author barely mentions the problems of corruption so evident to other commentators. He chastises the IMF for ham handed handling of bank and corporate restructuring and failure to prevent sharp increases in interest rates during the Asian Contagion. |
A dysfunctional banking system and lack of reliable stock markets and suitable protections for creditors and minority ownership interests are large parts of the answer as to why the region's high savings rates did not provide adequately for its capital needs. |
|
However, the "moral hazard" problem and other
systemic weaknesses in IMF operations are usefully reemphasized by the author in
relation to the Asian Contagion.
He deplores the fact that the short crisis was so sharp (but
does not address the question of whether avoiding the sharpness would have
lengthened its duration). |
Malaysia: |
Malaysia responded far more
effectively to the panic by rejecting IMF funds and advice than did Thailand or
Indonesia which took IMF funds and implemented IMF reforms. (The quality of
implementation in these latter two nations was very poor.) & |
The capital controls - carefully limited - did not frighten away foreign investors as feared. Investors are more interested in tomorrow's prospects than in yesterdays problems. |
Malaysia, too,
restructured weak banks and corporations, but did this with modest temporary
capital controls - replaced by temporary exit taxes on transfers of capital
abroad but applied only to residents and foreign portfolio investors. It also maintained low
interest rates and did not put itself through an austerity wringer. |
India and China:
India grew at 5% and China at 8% despite the economic downturn all around them |
Both India and China have capital controls and
escaped the Asian Contagion. India grew at 5% and China at 8% despite the
economic downturn all around them during the Asian Contagion.
|
China responded in a Keynesian way with substantially increased spending on infrastructure - something that was clearly needed and beneficial in its own right. (In Japan, spending on infrastructure of dubious benefit has failed to restore economic growth.) Stiglitz concludes:
|
|
Korea and Thailand:
The relative success of Korea is attributed to its rejection of certain IMF prescriptions and its active role in shaping corporate restructuring and banking reform. |
Korea's robust recovery is
contrasted with the sluggish recovery of Thailand. The author attributes the relative success of
the former to its rejection of certain IMF prescriptions and its active role in
shaping corporate restructuring and banking reform. |
Asian Contagion outcomes: |
The Asian Contagion panic and economic contraction did
what would be expected under standard economic theory, Stiglitz acknowledges. |
Financial
regulatory systems and financial institutions have been improved and economic
competitiveness has improved. "Some of the worst aspects of corruption, the
so-called crony capitalism, will have been checked." (None of this would
have occurred without the lash of market discipline in hard times.) |
|
The IMF now admits that it made serious mistakes
in its policy mix with respect to the Asian Contagion. These include premature
liberalization of capital markets, fiscal policy mistakes, and the manner of
bank restructuring in Indonesia. However, it has not signed on to Keynesian
views of appropriate monetary policy in panic situations, and it offers no
explanation why its econometric models performed so badly. (But NO
macroeconomic econometric models have ever worked in volatile periods - because
they are all inherently invalid.)
|
Summing up the Keynesian alternative: |
Instead of massive bailouts
- now universally criticized - Stiglitz advises a more flexible approach - on
Keynesian lines - but adjusted to each particular situation instead of being
applied in "one-size-fits-all" fashion. He candidly concedes that he
cannot be sure of the success of his suggested approach - but reasonably insists
its results couldn't be worse than those of the IMF approach during the Asian
Contagion. & |
These suggestions provide a useful summation of the author's most pertinent views on this complex subject.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
World Bank reforms: |
Instead of imposing conditions as a
prerequisite for assistance, the World Bank should select developing countries
"with a proven track record" and offer them assistance as an
inducement to continue with whatever they are doing that works. & |
Aid should be expanded, financed by the creation of "Special Drawing Rights" or systems of international taxation for exploitation of global resources - like fisheries. Debt relief is also important - especially for debts incurred by corrupt despotisms that have since been overturned.
Systems of global
governance are essential for problems that exceed national boundaries, the
author correctly notes. This
applies not only to the political issues that are addressed in the U.N. - or
economic issues addressed by the IMF, World Bank and WTO - but global
environmental and health issues. (The need for particular international agencies
limited to particular purposes is widely acknowledged.) |
United States industrial policy practices: |
Clinton administration use of influence on behalf of politically
influential American firms to gain favorable treatment from small nations at the
expense of their people is properly criticized by the author. France, too, is very active in this way - making
corrupt deals with corrupt governments. "There is, in fact, a long history
of 'unfair' contracts, which Western governments have used their muscle to
enforce." & |
U.S. "unfair trade" remedies have been intentionally designed in a way that facilitates abuse by special interests in the U.S. |
The shameful role of the Clinton administration -
principally its State Department and Treasury Department - in setting up a world
wide aluminum cartel to protect U.S. producers from competition - is set forth
by the author at some length as an example. (The Bush administration, with its
steel tariffs and agricultural subsidies, is rapidly accumulating its own list
of horrid policies.)
|
The stench of "crony capitalism" emanates also from Washington, D.C. |
These laws were even used to block a program for procuring
uranium from Soviet era nuclear weapons. The uranium was to be bought so that the nation could be protected
from possible loss of control over this dangerous material. The follies of the privatized U.S. Enrichment
Corporation, which was supposed to implement this program, are also set forth. As
the author points out, the stench of "crony capitalism" emanates also
from Washington, D.C. |
In his commentary on the U.S., the author accepts the common error of statistical analysis that has led so many uncritical critics to claim that the economic growth during the 1980s did not benefit the working poor.
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2003 Dan Blatt