BOOK REVIEW
How Capitalism Was Built
by
Anders Åslund
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 11, No. 6, 6/1/09
& |
The Soviet bloc unequivocally rejected socialism
in 1989. However, Anders Åslund points out in "How Capitalism Was Built:
The Transformation of Central and Eastern Europe, and Central Asia," the rates to reform of the 400 million people in 21 states varied generally by
region and particularly by state. |
Corruption and weaknesses in rule of law remain widespread problems in all the states from the Soviet bloc.
East Germany received vastly more help - from West Germany - and its economic growth remains stunted as a result. Its produce was priced out of the markets by a strong mark and was rendered totally non-competitive.
The 3 small Baltic EU transition states - Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania - have kept their governments small and thus enjoy high growth rates. |
The kaleidoscope of economic, political and social change that
has swept from Berlin to Vladivostok, is masterfully sketched and analyzed by Åslund
drawing on extensive studies that have during the last decade substituted
fact for mere theory or worse, mere ideological prejudgment.
|
There was no understanding of private property or the functioning of a rule of law legal system. There was no civil society. Nobody had any experience with competitive capitalist markets. Rent-seeking through the state was the only route to wealth that anybody understood.
The potential for "rents," defined as "profits in excess of the competitive level," was enormous as socialist economies collapsed. |
Nobody thought transformation would be easy, and it wasn't. The Communists had ruthlessly destroyed human capital throughout the bloc, so there was little understanding as to how to proceed. There was no understanding of private property or the functioning of a rule of law legal system. There was no civil society. Nobody had any experience with competitive capitalist markets. Rent-seeking through the state was the only route to wealth that anybody understood.
The potential for "rents," defined as "profits in
excess of the competitive level," was enormous as socialist economies
collapsed. |
Mismanaged state enterprises had to be transferred to private ownership in a system that lacked private capital and managerial capabilities.
Democracy and rule of law legal systems were also objectives but would be tenuous at best in the absence of a legally, economically and politically empowered civil society that could give them popular support.
The sellers market of chronic shortages under socialism became a buyers market of competing goods and services. |
The freeing of prices and trade was the obvious step required for a
functioning market. However, the initial lack of goods in the market meant
explosive inflation that had to be brought under control. Mismanaged state
enterprises had to be transferred to private ownership in a system that lacked
private capital and managerial capabilities. Massive change meant massive social
dislocation that had to be cushioned by the state. Democracy and rule of law
legal systems were also objectives but would be tenuous at best in the absence
of a legally, economically and politically empowered civil society that could
give them popular support.
|
CIS market economic systems have low taxes and liberal labor markets, whereas the 9 EU accession states struggle with the high welfare costs and rigid labor markets of the EU. |
Political transformation was far less successful. Only the EU transformation states built democratic systems. They did this by
adopting EU institutions. Rule of law legal systems proved even harder to
create. |
The transformation contraction: |
There was an immediate decline in economic output, as might be
expected with the collapse of the previous socialist system. However, the extent
of the collapse attributable to transformation has been grossly overstated, Åslund
explains. |
Production had collapsed and there was literally nothing in the shops to purchase. Work ceased because the money was worthless. Assertions that subsequent economic transformation in post-Soviet Russia caused economic collapse are thus ridiculous. |
Soviet economic statistics were awful. The economic collapse in Soviet Russia was
already startlingly complete
by 1991. Production had collapsed and there was literally nothing in the shops
to purchase. Work ceased because the money was worthless. Assertions that subsequent
economic transformation in post-Soviet Russia caused economic collapse are thus
ridiculous.
|
Most of the collapse occurred before transformation began. Much of the production decline that did occur - amounting to more than 20% of GDP - was in military production that was no longer needed.
Much of the rest of the decline was in output of such poor quality that nobody wanted it.
Gray market activities surged in Russia and the other CIS countries but were not counted in official statistics. |
Soviet production was always grossly overstated - its economic statistics a farce created by pervasive incentives to exaggerate production. Soviet growth rate claims were ultimately abandoned by Soviet economists. Most of the collapse occurred before transformation began. Much of the production decline that did occur - amounting to more than 20% of GDP - was in military production that was no longer needed. Military spending was slashed from 25% of GDP to 5% of GDP. Military spending was slashed to between 1% and 2% of GDP elsewhere in the Soviet bloc transition states. No alternative uses could be found for most of the military production resources. Much of the rest of the decline was in output of such poor quality that nobody wanted it.
Although imports were very expensive, Russian goods were so shoddy that they could not compete, so half of official consumer output just vanished. "The share of unsalable goods probably amounted to 29% of GDP in the last year of communism."
On the other hand, gray market activities surged in Russia and the other CIS countries but were not counted in official statistics. Estimates have been based on electricity consumption.
|
Contraction due to the elimination of waste is actually desirable, and "socialism was a system of waste."
Roughly 50% of the recorded Soviet bloc transformation slump was fictitious, with wide variations between nations.
Recovery could not begin until inflation was controlled. |
Careful empirical analysis since the fall of the Soviet Union has revealed the gross statistical distortions that fooled academic and CIA analysts alike. In 1990, CIA figures for the Soviet GDP were 43% of the U.S. level at purchasing power parity. This was quickly lowered to 32% - and household per capita consumption to 24% - of the U.S. level. East German GDP turned out to be just half the reported amount - just 30% of West German per capita GDP.
After all, contraction due to the elimination of waste is actually desirable, and "socialism was a system of waste."
Contraction from the elimination of hoarded inventory was also
desirable. This, too, was huge - calculated at as much as two thirds of the
reduction in Polish GDP in 1990, reducing the measured decline from 11% to less
than 5%. Recognizing the unreliability of the statistics, Åslund reasonably
estimates that roughly 50% of the recorded Soviet bloc transformation slump was
fictitious, with wide variations between nations. |
Gradualism versus shock therapy:
Gradual transformation was actually attempted for two years by Mikhail Gorbachev until he realized that the omnipotent Party bureaucracy was capable of blocking all reforms in Russia.
& |
China's ongoing successful gradual transformation looms large as an example of a less chaotic route to transformation. However, this route was actually attempted for two years by Mikhail Gorbachev until he realized that the omnipotent Party bureaucracy was capable of blocking all reforms in Russia. In Russia the political situation was radically different than in China, Åslund explains.
|
"All measures indicate that as radical and early a transition as possible yielded the best economic and social results."
"The evidence is overwhelming that early, radical, and comprehensive reforms constituted the best option. Almost all the arguments for gradual reforms - - - have been empirically disproved."
"Because of unwillingness to sell cheaply to local businessmen, large plants have most died in Central Europe either in the hands of inept foreign investors, more often in protracted, unproductive state ownership." |
Transformation in the Soviet bloc was so onerous precisely because socialist management had failed so completely. Everything was falling apart. There were few economic assets worth saving. Nobody knew how to proceed, but transformation was essential regardless of hardship.
|
State enterprises were hurriedly sold for a song in a privatization process that was rough and frequently corrupt, but these privatized enterprises have since paid far more in taxes than any conceivable original price that might have been realized. |
The private sector provided most of the growth that followed transformation.
State enterprises were hurriedly sold for a song
in a privatization process that was rough and frequently corrupt, but these privatized
enterprises have since paid far more in taxes than any conceivable original
price that might have been realized. The longer assets remained in state hands,
the more human and physical capital was destroyed by state mismanagement. "But
it does matter that a privatization be perceived as legitimate, so that the
resulting property rights are politically recognized" and publicly
supported. |
The Stalinist system imposed throughout the Soviet
bloc is described by Åslund. |
|
Some pockets of private enterprise persisted but remained small
except in Polish agriculture. The longer the system lasted, the more
dysfunctional it became. "This system left a problematic legacy, such as
the extreme centralization of decision making and the actual supervision by the
Party, which was an extralegal body."
|
Power was deconcentrated to lower levels of the Party and state hierarchy, rendering the Soviet Union a dictatorship of industrial ministers and regional first Party secretaries. |
The slow, protracted decline of the Soviet system prior to its dramatic collapse is sketched by Åslund. In the end, Gorbachev took power in a system incapable of adjusting to modern technology or keeping pace with U.S. military modernization. The Soviet elite became increasingly aware of the system's failings. Various efforts at reform were attempted in Poland, Czechoslovakia and Hungary, but the Stalinist system thwarted Gorbachev's reform efforts in the 1980s. Stalin was indeed a totalitarian tyrant in complete control, but by the 1980s, all that had changed.
Gorbachev no longer had the power to force reform from the top down
into the Party bureaucracy. He thus had to attack and break down the influence of the Communist
Party, which by
that time had no public legitimacy or support. Unfortunately, this just left state
enterprise managers in total control of their entities, and they proceeded to
steal what they controlled. (See. Gaddis, "The Cold
War," at segments on "The end of the Cold War" and "The
end of the Soviet Union," and Kotkin, "Armageddon
Averted,") |
When oil production began to decline and oil prices fell sharply in the 1980s, the financial situation in Russia became "beyond salvation." |
Toward the end, inflation reached ruinous levels in the Soviet Union and Poland, and many of the Central European states fell deeply into debt. Nobody wanted to lend money to the hard-line government in Czechoslovakia, and Romania was squeezing its people to repay its debt. East Germany had no public legitimacy. Bulgaria was deeply in debt. Hungary succeeded in reforming itself into a socialist market economy with manageable macroeconomic policies, and Czechoslovakia managed to maintain a static but functioning "Brezhnevian economy." When oil production began to decline and oil prices fell sharply in the 1980s, the financial situation in Russia became "beyond salvation."
|
After the fall:
& |
There were significant political and economic
differences in the six Central European transformation states and the 15
transformation states that spun off from the Soviet Union. Åslund describes the
differences that played a major role in the various initial transformation experiences. |
Three states from the Soviet Union remained rigidly communist, the three Baltic states and Armenia and Georgia had well established national identities, but the Muslim states did not. Old conflicts and resentments surfaced immediately. The new republican parliaments refused to send tax revenues to Moscow, dooming the Soviet Union. By the end of 1991, the Soviet Union was gone - not with a bang, thank god, but with barely a whimper. Only in Tajikistan and Chechnya was there serious internal conflict. (The breakup could as readily have been like that in Yugoslavia - but it would have involved major military units, some of which possessed atomic weapons.)
|
There was no recipe for transition from communism
to capitalism. It was like making an aquarium out of fish soup. |
|
Seven decades of autocratic socialism in many of the Soviet
bloc countries had destroyed all human capital - all know-how -
about market system operations. In Central Europe, four decades of Soviet
domination had severely degraded market capabilities. The stakes were enormous,
and the intellectual controversy quickly reached fever pitch. |
Radical reform consisted of macroeconomic stabilization to halt inflation, deregulation of prices and markets to get people to produce goods and services again, privatization and a social safety net to cushion the inevitable economic turmoil and hardships as the economy worked its way out of its socialist morass. |
It began in Poland with the liberalization of food prices in September, 1989, prior to the development
of the Washington Consensus list.. There was an
immediate 40% surge in inflation. Radical reform consisted of macroeconomic
stabilization to halt inflation, deregulation of prices and markets to get
people to produce goods and services again, privatization and a social safety
net to cushion the inevitable economic turmoil and hardships as the economy
worked its way out of its socialist morass. There was no idea of how best to
implement privatization.
|
The old communist state apparatus was an unmitigated disaster and had to be broken quickly and completely regardless of fallout. The state bureaucracy had to be stripped of economic power.
Only market prices could create accurate economic signals and production incentives, only imports could quickly end shortages. Inflationary expectations had to be quickly broken. |
There were many tactical differences among these European
transition states, as one would expect. Floating exchange rates
predominated, but Poland, Czechoslovakia and Estonia quickly pegged their rates.
Poland and Czechoslovakia adopted strict wage controls. The amounts of
international assistance and the pace of privatization varied widely. |
Gradual reform:
& |
There were wide differences among those advocating
gradual reform, also as might be expected. Most were in denial of the extent
of economic failure of the Soviet system and many retained unspoken socialist
views. (John K. Galbraith remained an apologist for Soviet economic performance
well into the 1990s. See, "Modern Advocacy Scholars"
at segment on "Ideological blinders.") |
Gradual market price liberalization in Russia was disastrous and led to "mass rent seeking by prominent members of the Nomenklatura." Free market prices would greatly reduce opportunities for corruption and rent seeking. |
The economic fallout from gradual reform in China and Hungary
had been much milder and provided support for proponents of gradual reform.
There was also powerful support from the rent-seekers who permeated Soviet bloc
economic elites and who wished to extend their period of maximum rent-seeking
opportunities. However, only in Hungary had any effort at gradual reform ever
been successfully maintained in the Soviet bloc.
|
Radical reform proved far less costly than expected by the gradualists, support for democratization was based on more than just economic prosperity and was sustained despite radical reform difficulties, and the capabilities of government administered alternatives to the markets never even remotely approached the levels expected by the gradualists. |
The Soviet Party and state were beyond reform. Collapse was the
only alternative. China and Russia were simply not comparable. |
Western Keynesian economists like John K. Galbraith, Vassily Leontiff and James Tobin who supported state guided gradualism involving the continuation of the state planning apparatus and protection and subsidization of the industrial dinosaurs. They ignored the malfunctioning of the state and the corruption and rent seeking of its bureaucracy and instead blamed corruption on privatization. |
Only East Germany adopted complete institutional reforms before
economic reforms, since it came quickly under the West German system. However,
"East Germany stands out as one of the most costly and least successful
transitions."
|
Transformation became a "war for and against rent seeking." The rent-seekers won in the CIS countries but lost in the Baltics and Central Europe. |
It was the rent seekers, however, who were the most vocal critics of radical reform. Transformation became a "war for and against rent seeking." The rent-seekers won in the CIS countries but lost in the Baltics and Central Europe.
Gorbachev's gradual, partial reforms created a "hothouse of rent seeking."
Åslund explains how each of the Gorbachev reforms was undone for the
benefit of the state enterprise managers.. By 1991,
the Soviet budget deficit had exploded to at least 20% of GDP. It was financed by an
explosion of monetary inflation resulting inevitably in price hyperinflation and
economic and political collapse. |
"The most prominent source of rent seeking in the public mind was privatization, but rent seeking peaked in 1992 when privatization had hardly started." |
Gradualism provided time for vested interests to generate support for remaining barriers to trade.
Ultimately, the rent seekers supported reform to secure their gains.
Russian transformation was hardly ideal by anyone's account,
and its budgetary, monetary and exchange rate policies were clearly
unsustainable. |
The financial collapse of 1998:
& |
The market reforms of the
transformation effort became a scapegoat for Russia's 1998 financial crisis. Economists like Joseph Stiglitz
quickly pronounced Russian transformation a failure and rushed to blame a variety of transformation policies
for the crisis - just as Russia began a remarkable eight year period of
macroeconomic stability and 7% GDP growth. (A low GDP base at the start and
rising prices for oil and other commodities that Russia exported were a big help
in achieving this high growth rate. However, the achievement is nevertheless
impressive.) |
The basic causes of the financial crisis were actually the large budget deficits and dysfunctional fiscal arrangements.
Scholarly studies of Russia's transformation period almost unanimously blame its 1998 relapse on gaps in its reform effort rather than on some blind "market fundamentalism" reform push. |
Stiglitz blamed "market fundamentalism" and the radical reform effort. (See, Stiglitz, "Globalization and its Discontents," at segment on "Transformation economies and the Russian crisis.") The IMF and U.S. Treasury interventions were condemned. An overvalued ruble, barter systems that accounted for more than 50% of industrial sales by 1998 and facilitated tax avoidance and rent seeking, and the public and private debt burden were all blamed.
As so often in these financial crises, the basic causes were actually the large
budget deficits and dysfunctional fiscal arrangements. The Russian budget was deeply in debt - by about 8% of GDP - and
highly dependent on short term credits from abroad. With the preceding Asian Contagion
financial crisis, servicing costs for this short term debt soared, and foreign
money fled. The price of oil plummeted to $10 per barrel. After obtaining some
initial international support, it became apparent that Russia's finances were
untenable and default inevitable.
|
Creative destruction from the 1998 crisis:
& |
The Russian financial collapse of 1998 turned out to be a
turning point. Rather than being a force for social disruption and economic
chaos as many theorists feared, the crisis turned out to be a force for economic reform and
growth throughout much of the CIS. The Russian people yet once again stoically
absorbed their travails. |
Rather than being a force for social disruption and economic chaos as many theorists feared, the crisis turned out to be a force for economic reform and growth throughout much of the CIS. |
There was a reversal of fortune after 1998. Twelve laggard CIS
countries began to grow twice as fast as the four EU Central European countries. Until 1998,
the best economic results were achieved by the radical reformers in Central
Europe and the Baltic nations and Armenia, Georgia and Kyrgistan. Growth in the CIS nations was slow or minimal. Afterwards, the best
growth rates were achieved in the CIS nations. |
As government contracted, economic growth accelerated. Tax rationalization led to low, flat taxes. "As tax rates fell, tax administration was simplified, corruption diminished, and tax collection improved." |
A wave of creative destruction was loosed upon the CIS states. The markets were, as always, ruthless and inexorable. Many of the CIS countries suffered financial crises in 1998 similar to
that in Russia, and similarly had to drastically cut their budgets because they
couldn't borrow any more. Budget cuts amounted to 25% or more in the midst of
the economic contraction.
Nine CIS countries became market-driven economies with about 64% of
GDP coming from their private sectors. Public expenditures dropped to about 20%
less than the Central European states. As government contracted, economic growth
accelerated. Tax rationalization led to low, flat taxes. "As tax rates
fell, tax administration was simplified, corruption diminished, and tax
collection improved."
|
Shock therapy was at last forced upon Russia - and the Russian economy began to thrive. "Suddenly, the Russian government undertook all those measures it should have carried out in 1992." |
In Russia, the ruble plunged and inflation soared. There was no capital available for bonds. A reluctant Russian parliament was forced to make drastic spending cuts, and regional governments were forced to cut enterprise subsidies. Russian enterprise sector subsidies amounted to 16.3% of GDP in 1998, with similar results in Ukraine and Moldova. The worst 50% of the banks failed, and so the payments system improved. Shock therapy was at last forced upon Russia - and the Russian economy began to thrive. "Suddenly, the Russian government undertook all those measures it should have carried out in 1992."
Russia's intractable budget deficit suddenly disappeared and was replaced by budget surpluses, "enterprise subsidies were cut and barter and offsets were eliminated." Social transfers were reduced and the central government began receiving a larger share of the tax revenues collected by the regional governments. Tax reform brought tax simplification and lower rates. There were a variety of other market reforms. International payments turned positive and Russia began accumulating substantial dollar reserves.
In Russia, however, there was a downside to such crises. The political
elites have taken these opportunities to renationalize major economic entities. Banks were
renationalized in 1998 (and major industries are being renationalized during the
current Credit Crunch crisis). |
Gradual and partial deregulation was not designed to minimize
social suffering, as its intellectual supporters expected. Instead, it was
controlled by the ruling elites and designed to "maximize the rents of the select few in the
ruling elites." |
|
Regulatory barriers create high transaction costs. Radical reform stripped away the regulatory barriers to permit a real market economy.
"Unemployment reflects the severity of labor market regulations. As we would expect, Central Europe has steadily had the highest unemployment in the region" - as high as 20% in 2001. Because of the extensive subsidization and social regulation from West Germany, East German unemployment immediately rose to 35% in 1991. "A veritable social welfare trap had been created at a huge cost to West German taxpayers."
The labor market was freer but chaotic in the CIS states. Wage arrears, wages paid in kind and wages totally not paid were widespread. Skilled workers were in short supply and so fared well. However, socialism was controlled by the Nomenklatura and it was they, not the workers, who rose to dominate the workers and the state and to take control of their enterprises. "They pretend to pay me and I pretend to work" was a common attitude among the workers. Workers stayed put for the social benefits provided by their formal employers but sought temporary work in the underground economy. Eventually, deregulation and regulation that was not enforced liberalized labor markets in many CIS nations. |
The cause of inflation was, of course, always government expansion of
the money supply to finance government deficits, but propaganda successfully
pinned the blame on the reformers and undermined public support for reform. Initial reform efforts in Russia failed for lack of Western
stabilization assistance and insufficient political power to stand up to the
Nomenklatura, Åslund asserts.
"All the mistakes that had been made after the dissolution of the
Habsburg Empire [after WW-I] were repeated with the ruble zone." All the
CIS states that experienced ruble zone inflation failed to establish democratic
systems. The 1993 split-up between the Czech Republic and Slovakia, on the other
hand, was quickly followed by establishment of national currencies and monetary
stabilization was maintained. |
|
"Only after taxes have been reduced and simplified can tax administration be reformed."
Capital flight began during Soviet times and accelerated prior to deregulation and currency convertibility. Indeed, it was capital flight that forced deregulation and currency convertibility. Usually, it was the market pressures that ultimately caused financial crises and forced stabilization and brought capital flight to an end. |
A vast tax bureaucracy at multiple government levels enforcing a bewildering array of taxes had quickly developed as a force for corruption and extortion and as an obstacle to enterprise. When governments were forced by financial crisis to drastically cut expenditures, they were also able to drastically cut and rationalize taxation, and rapid recovery and faster growth rates soon followed.
The absence of a functioning financial system remained an obstacle for transformation economies for several years. The simple receipt and making of payments became a severe problem. Sellers had to insist on prepayment because there were no legal tools for collecting claims, ineffective debt collection and unreliable courts and no bankruptcy laws. Except in Poland, payment by bank transfers was mandatory so taxes could be collected, but commercial banks slowed check clearance to profit from the float. Inflation expectation further induced delays in payments. Only after the socialist payments systems were abolished was stabilization achieved.
Capital flight was an immediate problem, but it was clearly not
caused by deregulation - Joseph Stiglitz to the contrary notwithstanding.
Capital flight began during Soviet times and accelerated prior to deregulation
and currency convertibility. Indeed, it was capital flight that forced
deregulation and currency convertibility. Usually, it was the market pressures that ultimately caused financial
crises and forced the stabilization that brought capital flight to an end. |
Privatization was varied and often chaotic. It
could hardly have been otherwise. Over 150,000 substantial and hundreds of
thousands of small enterprises and millions of apartments and houses were
privatized in a decade. |
|
Radical privatization reduced corruption while gradualness permitted elites to entrench themselves and block progress. Privatization generated support for the creation of rule of law legal systems which take years to mature. Radical reform economies grew fastest and quick economic radical reforms supported democratic reforms.
"The state would have lost greatly if it had retained
these companies and privatized them later, regardless of the eventual sale
price." |
Criticism of privatization has been vitriolic, premature and
usually wrong (and generally biased by left wing theory and ideology).
Radical privatization reduced corruption while gradualness permitted elites to
entrench themselves and block progress. Privatization generated support for the
creation of rule of law legal systems which take years to mature. Radical reform
economies grew fastest and quick economic radical reforms supported democratic
reforms. There remains widespread envy for those who became wealthy, and a sense
that not enough was paid for transferred assets that ignores the growing tax
revenues flowing from those assets.
For example, the majority stake in Yukos oil company was privatized
for $310 million when perhaps $4 to $5 billion was feasible. However, by 2000,
Yukos paid $6 billion in taxes and had a market capitalization in 2003 of $45
billion due to the success of its private management. (Oil price fluctuations
played a major role in this outcome, but the point is nevertheless well taken.) |
Rapid change of management was one of the most beneficial results of economic reform.
New startups were the most aggressive in realizing the opportunities for growth. |
New startups have performed best, firms privatized to outsiders
performed better than those privatized to insiders, those privatized to
employees were as bad as state enterprises. Outside managers performed better
than inside incumbent socialist managers. Foreign ownership performed best among
privatized firms other than the major industrial dinosaurs. Rapid change of management was one of the most beneficial
results of economic reform. |
There is a wild West aspect to transformation stock markets due to poor regulation. Most Russian and Eastern European stock trading has migrated to London where it facilitates financing and enterprise restructuring.
|
Justification for gradualism was based on several erroneous assumptions.
|
|
The sanctity of property rights is crucial. The weakest aspect
of radical reform was the widespread doubts about the legitimacy of the property
rights gained. This has led to reprivatizations from oligarchs in Ukraine, and
renationalizations of successful companies by Putin in Russia that greatly
benefits the top officials in the Russian government. Speed was essential because it had to be completed before the
communist power elites could recover enough to dominate or thwart the process.
Theft and asset stripping by state management grew to alarming proportions,
emphasizing the need for speedy privatization. "What is not privatized will
be stolen" became conventional wisdom. ("What everybody owns, nobody
owns" is another common version of this wisdom that manifests itself most
notoriously in "the tragedy of the commons" situations.) However,
without established markets or functioning accounting systems, there was no way
to set reasonable prices. The results were necessarily chaotic. |
|
The methods of privatization varied widely, and there was considerable
and varied compromise and accommodation among the power elite. This often kept
inept communist managers and inefficient labor arrangements in place. The old
ministries and state enterprise managers transformed their power structure into
monopolies and holding companies. |
Intellectual support for efforts at applying equitable methods quickly broke down into the art of the possible that recognized the need to accommodate power elites. |
The process of reallocating capital from political to economic
hands was facilitated by the blossoming of stock markets and other financial
institutions. Unfortunately, the risks of this financial chaos deterred the
direct foreign investment that could have quickly brought in needed expertise.
With the exception of Hungary where earlier reforms had already been effective,
the best strategy was to simply give the state assets away. They had little
value in the incompetent hands of the states, and successful private
restructuring efforts led quickly to private profits and tax revenues that
dwarfed the highest possible sales price.
Either sales to outsiders or mass privatization with vouchers
predominated in most states. Management-employee buyouts predominated in four
states and there was no privatization in Belarus and Turkmenistan. Intellectual
support for efforts at applying equitable methods quickly broke down into the
art of the possible that recognized the need to accommodate power elites. |
Spontaneous privatization by enterprise management was widespread. This was called "Nomenklatura
grabbing."
Transparency suffered and corrupt deals were widespread. Some initial public
offerings (IPOs) were undertaken in Poland, Hungary and Estonia, which were the
most institutionally advanced transformation nations, but were not feasible
elsewhere.
|
|
Voucher privatization was popular, widespread and far simpler than
IPOs. Vouchers were distributed to the public to start a market for private
property. In small firms, workers were sometimes made shareholders. Sales at
market prices were widely opposed because only communist era power elites and
outsiders had the financial capital needed.
The same can be said for insider manager and employee privatization.
Only in Poland did employees gain significant advantages. Managers paid little
for their "buyouts." Russian energy companies became the basis for
huge private fortunes. However, these privatizations were fast and easy and
created legitimate property rights. Unfortunately, they also entrenched
incumbent incompetents. |
Land and housing privatization:
& |
The privatization of agricultural land,
commercial real estate and housing varied widely with the characteristics of
individual countries. Restitution of housing and agricultural land was common in
East and Central Europe - especially
in East Germany - where old land title registries had been maintained. Courts
were clogged with millions of claims in East Germany and restitution claims delayed construction
projects everywhere. Since communism was an affliction for everyone, particular legal rights were elsewhere not recognized. In
CIS nations, occupants were allowed to take possession. |
Privatization of commercial real estate was far more difficult.
It often took years to unify all rights in a single state agency so they could
be transferred to private hands. |
Entrepreneurs:
& |
Small enterprise was already flourishing in Hungary
and Poland in the 1980s. It blossomed quickly in the EU transition states. In
CIS states, governments insisted on "helping" small entrepreneurs - in
exchange for commissions, fees, regulations and corrupt practices. Small
enterprise was kept stunted by ubiquitous corrupt CIS
bureaucracies. |
"As much of the socialist production was value detracting, much of the socialist organizational capital was negative." |
Entrepreneurs in Central Europe quickly built substantial companies, contributing 33% of GDP as early as 1995. Economic liberalization with a low lump sum tax began in Kyrgyzstan in 1996 and Ukraine in 1998 with immediate success. Wherever heavy restrictions remained, the underground economy thrived.
|
A brave attempt is made to describe societal
impacts, but Åslund candidly acknowledges the unreliability of the
statistics. He discusses impacts on incomes, living standards and inequality;
health care, longevity and infant mortality; demographics and migration;
education; welfare, pension systems and subsidies. |
|
The possibilities for individual advancement in a market economy probably played a major role in dividing the Russian Communist Party and bringing down the Soviet Union.
It took severe economic crisis to drive market reforms in the autocratic transformation states, but where economic reform had been slow or delayed, power elites were able to prevent democratization. |
The picture is complex but widely improving in reform
transformation states, rendering incompetent all instant analyses by
transformation critics. The old power elites and
rising middle class reap most of the social spending benefits, much of which
disappears into the bureaucracy. In the low income CIS countries, remittances
from abroad far exceed welfare spending. Everywhere, government social agencies
prove harder to reform than private economic entities.
Democracy proved crucial for early market reform. Democracy has served
as an effective if hardly absolute check on corruption and rent seeking.
Democracy proved to be the best guarantee that the interests of the people would
take precedence over the interests of a rent seeking power elite. During the
initial half decade, the extent of democracy coincided with the extent of market
reform. It took severe economic crisis to drive market reforms in the autocratic
transformation states, but where economic reform had been slow or delayed, power
elites were able to prevent democratization. |
Communists "stayed both strong and unreformed where market-oriented economic transformation was slow." |
There is little
appetite for a return to communism despite all transition difficulties,
In Hungary and Poland, where old communist
parties receive more than 20% of the vote, they have become thoroughly market
oriented. Elsewhere, they help block the completion of market reforms and
support the interests of the rent seeking elites. Communists "stayed both
strong and unreformed where market-oriented economic transformation was
slow." |
Where political parties were forbidden or slow to form, democracy was weak.
Nationalism was a strong contributing factor when tied to economic reform. |
The formation and participation of strong political parties has
proven to be an essential feature of successful democratic reform. Where
political parties
were forbidden or slow to form, democracy was weak. Proportional representation
encouraged the formation of parties, but a threshold of about 5% was essential
to weed out groups with minimal support. After a couple of years, the initial
hardships of transformation splintered reformist parties and drove them from
power.
There is actually little academic guidance for the creation of a
sustainable and effective democracy. There are no widely held professional views
among political scientists. They did not rush to Soviet bloc countries to offer
political transformation advice as did the many economists who offered economic
transformation advice. Only support for and monitoring of democratic elections
was widely offered. Only imposition of EU institutions on EU transformation
states proved widely effective.
|
Lawlessness has since declined, but has in essence been taken over by increasingly effective but still corrupt police forces. Judicial systems remain ineffective. |
Lawlessness and corruption quickly exploded in the CIS states with the breakup of the Soviet empire, as might be expected. Lawlessness has since declined, but has in essence been taken over by increasingly effective but still corrupt police forces. Judicial systems remain ineffective. As with democracy, there was no rush of legal experts from the West offering advice on how nations with no relevant knowledge or traditions could establish an effective and independent legal system. Only the American Bar Association offered any advice and help. The EU transition states had EU civil law legal traditions to fall back on.
|
Judicial independence was unfortunately accompanied by judicial corruption, but throughout East and Central Europe, the public is using its courts, transparency is improving - and so are the courts. |
Legislation was different. A vast array of legislative initiatives blossomed quickly with intense advice from U.S. and EU sources. Legal rights and protections for property and investments in some instances now exceed those available in the West. Enforcement through the courts has improved most in the EU transformation states. There are 170,000 pages of EU legislation that is required for EU states. Still, enforcement in the courts remain well below EU standards.
Private arbitration courts provide a widely used and effective
substitute for resolving commercial disputes. Judicial independence was
unfortunately accompanied by judicial corruption, but throughout East and
Central Europe, the public is using its courts, transparency is improving - and
so are the courts. |
Democracy, deregulation, transparency, privatization and reductions in public expenditures and subsidies all tend to reduce opportunities for corrupt practices in the bureaucracy. The tax system and budget practices generate numerous opportunities for corruption that require constant attention. |
The corruption and crime that quickly afflicted transformation
states is analyzed at some length by the author. Democracy, deregulation,
transparency, privatization and reductions in public expenditures and subsidies
all tend to reduce opportunities for corrupt practices in the bureaucracy. The
tax system and budget practices generate numerous opportunities for corruption
that require constant attention. Åslund provides clear advice concerning
effective reform, but the politics of reform inevitably has many pitfalls. |
In the Hobbesian transition environment, as
in the 19th century U.S., a few men were shrewd enough to acquire and
rationalize vast industrial empires. |
|
Oligarchic control of major enterprises is far more common around the world than the diffuse corporate ownership in Anglo-Saxon nations. |
Such men were called "robber barons" in the 19th century U.S. In Russia, Ukraine and Kazakhstan, they were mostly engineers and are called "oligarchs." Åslund analyzes the similarities. He points out that oligarchic control of major enterprises is far more common around the world than the diffuse corporate ownership in Anglo-Saxon nations. The ability to navigate the corrupt relations with government agencies and rationalize vast assets make the oligarchs especially useful in transformation economies.
Oligarchs respond rationally to their economic, political and legal
environment. The problem is how to eliminate their abusive behavior without
undermining property rights generally. Only competition achieves any substantial
disciplinary success, and competition was the weapon of choice of Theodore
Roosevelt a century ago. Regulation is a comparatively weak reed and is subject
to industry capture. In Russia, renationalization of major financial and
industrial entities repeats all the failures of socialism.
|
It is populism, not socialism, that is now the main threat to political and economic freedom - capitalism and democracy. (This is always true for capitalist and democratic systems.) For the present, the requirements for macroeconomic stability are not the primary populist targets, as they are in Latin America. This generation of transformation peoples has had its lesson in runaway inflation. The primary populist target in transformation states is property rights. But the success of Western capitalism is based on the acceptance of property rights.
|
& |
Putin's popularity is at present the only source of legitimacy for the Russian government.
|
The reform administration of Yegor Gaidor under Boris Yeltsin
quickly fell from power in June 1992. The Bush (I) administration had failed to
provide the financial support that might have kept it in power. The Gaidor
administration was replaced
by old-style Soviet industrialists headed by Viktor Chernomyrdin. |
The CIS states:
& |
Longer periods under communism, lack of
access to outside markets, the "oil curse," and a legacy of autocratic
governance are all contributing factors undermining democratic prospects in CIS
states. |
Within a decade, except for the three non-reformers, all transition countries were under IMF supervision and had inflation under control. Most IMF funds have been repaid and most transition nations maintain relations with the IMF. |
Within the 12 CIS nations other than Russia, trade
autarky prevailed. There were repeated efforts to create trade and customs
unions, but they were defeated by domestic protectionist interests. Trade within the CIS dropped 70% by
1994. Not until 2005 did the EU offer some CIS members closer economic and
political relationships under its European Neighborhood Policy. The outcome
remains to be seen, but by that time CIS international trade levels had already
begun to increase. |
Conclusion:
& |
Mass privatization works, Åslund concludes. Flat
income taxes at low rates work. Gradualism doesn't work in states with weak institutions.
In deregulation and macroeconomic stabilization, the greater the rigor and
speed, the better, regardless of immediate hardship. Delay multiplies the power
of those in opposition. |
Reforms that were passed through parliamentary processes gain legitimacy where presidential decrees don't. |
Early parliamentary elections were important. Reforms that were passed through parliamentary processes gain legitimacy where presidential decrees don't. There remains no general theory for establishing democracy or a rule of law legal system, and these remain the weak points in the transformation states. (As stated above, these systems may be too idiosyncratic for any theory to be generally applicable.)
|
At present the populist wealth transfer policies of the democratic transformation states obstruct economic growth more than the high corruption levels in the CIS oligarchies. In the past, economically successful autocratic states - like S. Korea and Taiwan - have eventually become functioning democracies. Also, competition is pressuring EU states to lower tax rates and reduce regulatory burdens. So beneficial change is not an unlikely outcome.
|
|
Property rights and a widespread understanding of the benefits of
capitalism are essential for economic prospects, Åslund points out. At present,
both are very shaky in many transition states. Competition and pluralism are
essential for both political and economic rights. Privatization and deregulation
are essential for the control of corruption. |
|
"All the region's greatest shortfalls today are related to state failure: lack of democracy, a weak judicial system, poor law enforcement, corruption, slow public health care reform, and tardy public education reform." |
Financial assistance from the West was woefully inadequate, Åslund asserts. However, after 1993, there were great inflows of foreign direct investment. Also of great help were Western consultants on economic policy and legal reforms. Hundreds of new laws were drafted in every transformation nation. "Foreign advice was controversial because it was effective." The IMF and World Bank played major positive roles.
The World Bank and USAID provided assistance with the complex tasks of
privatization. The inevitable corruption and scandals notwithstanding, 65% of the
Soviet bloc economy was successfully privatized. Here, again, the effectiveness
of the assistance is reflected in the criticism the World Bank and USAID
received. Ineffective agencies don't draw criticism, because they are not taken
seriously.
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2009 Dan Blatt