NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOKS
Available at Amazon.com
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
ON THE PRINCIPLES OF
POLITICAL ECONOMY & TAXATION
by
David Ricardo
Page contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 6, No. 12, 12/1/04
In this review, modern terminology is
frequently used for the sake of clarity.
The word "corn," however, is often used to refer to the subsistence grains of England.
Introduction
The processes of market directed commerce:
& |
David Ricardo's
"On The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation" is concerned to a
large extent with the intellectual discourse on the subject of economics during
the first decades of the 19th century. Ricardo
essentially follows and expands upon the concepts of Adam Smith. The concepts of
Malthus and Say also appear prominently, and there are numerous references to
the works of other contemporaries. & |
It is the least fertile ground under cultivation - the least fertile mines in production - the subsistence wages of labor - that dictate prices, wages and the rent of landlords. |
While in general agreement with Smith with respect to basic
principles, Ricardo has many differences with respect to particular
market impacts and market adjustment sequences. Serious students thus must read the two treatises together.
See, Adam Smith,
"The Wealth of Nations (I)," and Adam Smith,
"The Wealth of Nations (II)." Ricardo's
agreements and differences with his other contemporaries - both as to matters of basic
principle and particular impact - permeate this book. Much of this discourse is of only historic
interest. Only the points of most current interest are covered in this
article. & The market adjustment process in relation to various economic factors is what Ricardo emphasizes. His numerous disagreements with Smith and others are generally over the particulars in this adjustment process. Consistently, he emphasizes how prices are set at the margins of supply and demand, but insists that in the long haul, it is the costs of supply that dictate market prices. It is the least fertile ground under cultivation - the least fertile mines in production - the subsistence wages of labor - that dictate prices, wages and the rent of landlords. & |
Population increases would always drive the wages of ordinary laborers back towards subsistence levels, no matter how productive and wealthy the rest of the economy should become.
Capital flows tend to equalize profit rates - subject to factors of risk and other difficulties. The rate of profits depends on the cheapness of labor, which depends on the cheapness of corn and other subsistence goods. However, with vast accumulations of capital, the amount of profits can increase even as the rate of profits declines. |
Ricardo was an ardent Malthusian. He expressed
great admiration for Malthus' "Essay on Population," but had several
disagreements with Malthus' work on rent.
|
All economies that are directed by competitive markets have comparative advantages - even if they have no absolute advantages in the goods they produce. |
Ricardo is a worthy follower of Adam Smith.
Ricardo's analyses would be a powerful factor in the reinstatement of the gold standard and the repeal of the Corn Laws and the establishment of free trade in the decades after his death. These economic reforms played a prominent role in the great surge of economic power and wealth enjoyed by 19th century Great Britain.
Smith had argued simply that it was foolish to
produce goods that others could produce and deliver more efficiently. Nations
should concentrate on that which they could produce with an absolute advantage.
|
Theories of value: |
The inherent conundrum of
value is explained by Ricardo. & |
Abundant items like air and water can have infinite value in use but no value in exchange, while scarce items like gold or diamonds can - in the beginning of the 19th century - have little value in use but great value in exchange.
Scarcity and labor embodied in commodities determine the levels around which exchange values fluctuate. |
He begins with Adam Smith's observations about the differences between value in use and value in exchange. Abundant items like air and water can have infinite value in use but no value in exchange, while scarce items like gold or diamonds can - in the beginning of the 19th century - have little value in use but great value in exchange. However, some utility in gratifying human wants is essential for value in exchange.
Scarcity and labor embodied in commodities determine the
levels around which exchange values fluctuate.
|
A precise method of calculating the "value" in commodities is impossible, but the embodied labor is the best general measure. |
"Value in exchange" is distinguished from "value in use" by equating "riches" and
"wealth" solely with use values, and economic "values"
solely with exchange values. Ricardo's explanations of these distinctions are a
part of his disputes with the views of contemporary writers.
|
There is no basic constant value for labor based on subsistence commodities.
Like Smith, Ricardo concentrates on exchange values, although he constantly emphasizes the ways in which labor values constrain exchange value fluctuations. |
Basic unskilled labor is itself a variable value,
Ricardo points out. It can only be measured "comparatively" at any
given moment - in proportion to other things - all of which are also in constant
flux. He rejects Smith's view that, regardless of momentary fluctuations above
and below subsistence levels, basic labor can be viewed as a constant because of its
essential relationship to subsistence levels.
Skill and intensity of labor are also variables, as are labor factors like hardship and ingenuity and training. Such labor factors are impossible to evaluate in the abstract, but are roughly reflected in market adjustments that respond to their intrinsic values "with sufficient precision for all practical purposes." Thus, like Smith, Ricardo concentrates on exchange values, although he constantly emphasizes the ways in which labor values constrain exchange value fluctuations.
|
All valuable items are constantly in flux absolutely and relative to each other - whether gold or corn or labor itself - due to flux in factors of supply and demand - long term and short term.
Exchange values in competitive markets fluctuate in response to shifts in the factors of supply and demand - albeit with some delay. |
There is no fixed measure of exchange values, either. All valuable items are constantly in flux absolutely and relative to each
other - whether gold or corn or labor itself - due to flux in factors of supply
and demand - long term and short term.
|
The production of durable capital - of fixed capital - is what permits economic growth, whereas production of immediate consumables does not - but fine distinctions at the margins are of little consequence. |
The value of physical capital assets is a part of
the value of the commodities produced by use of capital implements and facilities.
This, too, is related to the value of the labor expended in furnishing that
capital, and the rate at which those capital assets are expended.
Ricardo states the obvious:
|
The rate of profits is calculated against all capital
used - whether for wages, fixed capital or circulating capital or financial
capital. This is a fact so obvious that
Ricardo just assumes it - it requires no further elaboration - and is noted just
in a footnote. Profits are an ordinary and necessary expense of production. See,
"Profits and
Capitalist Productivity." |
|
Exchange values are measured in money terms.
Ricardo explains this at some length with reference to changes in relative
valuations between two commodities and between them and a third commodity - a
money commodity - which is presumably a commodity of stable valuation. Money - to
the extent that it is a commodity of stable valuation - permits calculation of
the extent to which value
relationship changes are due to each of the other
commodities.
|
Reliance on gold as his standard of measure is supported by the fact that - in spite of the vast influx in gold and silver from the new mines in America during the previous three centuries - the declines in purchasing power were slow enough to be practically imperceptible to those involved in the economy. This, and their other suitable qualities - hardness, malleability, divisibility - make gold and silver ideal as monetary units.
|
|
There is a time cost for commodities, physical capital assets and money. Time increases the value of commodities above the value attributable to labor, depending on the time costs of assets and money. |
Capital intensity determines how
wage fluctuations impact the relative fluctuations of value and prices of
different commodities. The distributional impact of a general change in wage
rates in a particular industry will vary depending on whether production is
or is not capital intensive. Production that relies more on capital is less
affected by wage rate changes, and that which relies less on capital is more
affected.
|
While increases in productivity can push basic wages somewhat above subsistence levels, the overall impact of increases in wealth and population is to drive wages back down towards and sometimes below subsistence levels. |
It is productivity increases that introduce the
greatest normal variability in absolute and relative valuations. Changes in
wages or profits can only have minimal impacts, but productivity increases can
carve major percentages off costs of a particular product. Of course, losses of
productivity - as when infrastructure breaks down - can substantially increase
costs. Ricardo thus
emphasizes productivity factors that decrease the amount of labor needed to get
goods to market, rather than changes in wage rates. |
Rent: |
Ricardo's concept of "rent" is confined
to the "use of the indestructible power of the soil." & |
"Rent" covers only the "use of the indestructible power of the soil." |
The capital invested in the land is a
separate subject. Ricardo
also distinguishes payments for mineral and timber rights. His definition of
"rent" is thus considerably narrower than that of Smith, and permits a
sharper analysis of the subject. He primarily discusses rents in relation to
agricultural lands producing the staple grains. & |
If capital improvements are permanent - such as the removal of trees or rocks or the draining of wetlands - rent will ultimately increase to absorb those benefits. |
Rent rises to absorb all the advantages of a
particular piece of property over alternative properties. In this
Ricardo agrees with Smith. Thus, the rate of profits remain equal - as widely
observed - whether for operations based on the least favorable property, which
can command no rent, or the most favorable, which commands substantial rents, or
any of the parcels in between. |
It is the profitably cultivated land that is least fertile - and thus pays no rent - that sets the price of corn.
It is the least efficiently provided items - as long as they are accepted in the market - that set the price. |
Prices are set at the margin. Thus, it is the profitably cultivated land that is least fertile - and thus pays no rent - that sets the price of corn.
The elimination of rent would not reduce the price of
corn. It would just transfer wealth from landlords to tenant farmers.
The "advantages of fertile over inferior lands - - -
[is] transferred from the cultivator, or consumer, to the landlord, yet, since
more labor is required on the inferior lands," and produce from the
inferior lands is needed
to meet market demand, "the comparative value" of that commodity will
be set at the margin of that produced by the least efficient producer. Its
value will rise in relation to other goods not similarly impacted.
|
Profits of tenant farmers must remain equal whether they work more or less fertile lands, with rents absorbing the difference. |
Increases in productivity - by reducing the extent of the less fertile lands that have to be cultivated to meet demand - will reduce rents on the more fertile lands that remain in cultivation. However, as wealth and population increase in response to these lower costs, the extent of lands under cultivation and the amount of rents will be restored. An increase in productivity thus initially harms landlords by reducing rents, until wealth and population growth can respond and bring marginal lands back into production.
Whatever reduces or increases the inequality of lands under cultivation reduces or increases rent. Moreover, as the greater demand brings more marginal lands into cultivation, the price of grains rises. The landlords holding more fertile lands absorb all the benefits, including much of the increase in the value of the grains produced. Profits of tenant farmers must remain equal whether they work more or less fertile lands, with rents absorbing the difference. |
The poorest mine that can be operated with the standard rate of profit pays no rent but regulates the rent chargeable on all the wealthier mines. |
Rents charged for mining rights are analyzed along
similar lines. The poorest mine that can be operated with the standard rate of
profit pays no rent but regulates the rent chargeable on all the wealthier
mines. |
Prices:
& |
Market prices are influenced by and
fluctuate around the natural price. While labor generally determines this
natural price, market prices adjust sensitively to applicable unstable factors
to regulate the competitive market economic system. & |
Capital knows no geographic boundaries and will
flow towards the most profitable uses in the system. By increasing and
decreasing profits, price fluctuations balance the whole system. They provide
the driving force that causes prices to tend to return towards their natural
levels. |
Wages:
& |
The natural price of labor rises and falls
only in line with fluctuations in the subsistence cost of living. This leaves
the wages of labor stuck - fluctuating around subsistence levels. & |
However, like Smith, Ricardo recognizes that English laborers during his times subsist at considerably higher levels than in previous periods. |
These subsistence levels are meager, indeed,
according to Ricardo. They are sufficient only to reproduce a stable population.
|
Productivity increases are recognized by Ricardo as a natural phenomenon of capitalist market economies. This can provide the constant expansion of capital that supports persistently higher wages and continuous population growth.
|
|
A "diminished rate of increase in population" can keep labor scarce and prosperous. |
Ricardo's long term outlook for labor is gloomy. The persistent population increase and the law of diminishing returns must ultimately drive wages back to subsistence levels. Productivity increases and capital expansion simply cannot indefinitely outrun population growth.
However, Ricardo actually did note the possibility. A
"diminished rate of increase in population," he noted, can keep labor
scarce and prosperous. |
The Poor Laws: |
Discussing the entitlement welfare
program of his day, Ricardo perceptively pointed out the unintended
consequences of such programs. & |
Welfare entitlements must increase poverty and impoverish society.
Entitlement programs tend to create dependencies, making their withdrawal difficult, painful, and even dangerous. |
The Poor Laws were benevolently established for the relief of poverty. However, Ricardo explained, such efforts must increase poverty. They suffer from costs that rise rapidly and without limit, and ultimately can bankrupt an economy.
Ricardo carefully notes that this should not be interpreted as criticism of efforts to relieve "temporary states of misery" such as may occur during periods of famine or economic recession. However, entitlement programs tend to create dependencies, making their withdrawal difficult, painful, and even dangerous. Fortunately, each local parish was responsible for its own Poor Law expenditures, giving each locality incentive to restrain program growth.
|
Profits:
& |
The profits of stock in
different industries have been shown to maintain a proportionate relationship to
each other and to fluctuate in the same degree and direction. & |
Profits are an ordinary and necessary cost of production, so a reduction beyond certain limits will bring all economic progress to a halt.
Ricardo notes that the subsistence levels of English workers are substantially higher than those of Irish workers and those who live in similarly impoverished lands. |
Rent, as narrowly defined by Ricardo, is an add-on
to the costs of wages and profits. It does not diminish either of them, but is
passed on as an addition to consumer costs.
However there is a natural limit to how far profit rates
can decline. Profits are an ordinary and necessary cost of production, so a
reduction beyond certain limits will bring all economic progress to a halt.
As Ricardo notes, the subsistence levels of English
workers are substantially higher than those of Irish workers and those who live
in similarly impoverished lands. This is substantial enough to provide some cushion
during recession periods even during Ricardo's times. (However, this still does not
lead him to doubt his essentially gloomy outlook for wage labor.) |
A small return on the vast capital in wealthy nations will far exceed in aggregate amount the high return on the meager capital in impoverished nations. However, the law of diminished returns always puts limits on capital accumulations. Thus, only productivity gains can provide prosperity at a constantly expanding rate. |
Because of diminishing returns, the constant increase in
population and wealth tends to increase nominal wages and reduce profit rates.
This is countered - (indeed, outweighed) - by rapid increases in productivity
that push down all costs - including subsistence costs - and thus force down
"natural" wage rates as well. |
International Trade and Comparative Advantage
The benefits of free trade: |
What are the economic
benefits of an extension of foreign trade? & |
"No country can long import, unless it also exports, or can long export unless it also imports." |
Foreign trade is a win-win proposition. Both exports and imports bestow benefits on trading nations. Indeed, it is equally essential to engage in both. International monetary flows and fluctuations, and the processes of comparative advantage, dictate that the two must go together. The need to conduct import-substitution manufacturing or agriculture will withdraw capital from export manufacture - a nation's most efficient economic activity - and apply it to considerably less efficient import-substituting commerce.
|
Importation of subsistence foods from more fertile lands abroad can materially increase economic limits. The reduction of subsistence costs reduces wages and rents, increases profits and capital accumulation and wealth and population. |
Arguments that favor the Corn
Laws - protectionist measures that shielded farmers from import competition
- are easily shredded by the author.
He repeatedly demonstrates how the importation of cheap grains - something that
would require repeal of the Corn Law protectionist measures - would increase the
wealth - the "riches" - of the nation.
Of course, change - any change - always inconveniences some people. It is such people that support the Corn Laws against the broader interests of the nation.
|
The benefits of foreign trade thus include an increase in living standards with an increase in the amount and variety of goods for consumption, and the ability to increase savings and capital accumulation without sacrificing consumption. These are the same impacts as for the domestic introduction of improved technology or infrastructure. It is the consumers that are the invariable beneficiaries. |
The benefits of free trade are profound but limited.
Some of these conclusions are dependent on Ricardo's basic theory that "the rate of profits can never be increased but by a fall in wages, and there can be no permanent fall of wages but in consequence of a fall of the necessaries on which wages are expended."
The benefits of foreign trade thus include an increase in
living standards with an increase in the amount and variety of goods for
consumption, and the ability to increase savings and capital accumulation
without sacrificing consumption. However, it "has no tendency to raise the
profits of stock" unless it involves the import of subsistence goods at
reduced prices. These are the same impacts as for the domestic introduction of
improved technology or infrastructure. It is the consumers that are the
invariable beneficiaries. |
Comparative advantage: |
Ricardo then provides his
explanation of comparative advantage - undoubtedly his most outstanding
contribution to economic theory. & |
|
In international trade, there are obstructions to
the rational flow of economic factors. Labor and even capital are obstructed at
international borders. There are variations in risk factors affecting the security of peoples
and their property. Climate and fertility characteristics vary in each nation.
Sociological characteristics vary widely. |
|
Even if Portugal could produce both wine and cloth more efficiently than England, it would still be more efficient for Portugal to concentrate on the product for which it has the greatest advantage - say, wine - and still procure its cloth from England in exchange for wine. Even if England had no absolute advantage, it would still have a comparative advantage in cloth with which it could engage profitably in foreign trade. By trade, both nations would wind up with more cloth and wine, and living standards would thus rise. |
Then, Ricardo takes this logic one step further. Even if Portugal could produce both wine and cloth more efficiently than England, it would still be more efficient for Portugal to concentrate on the product for which it has the greatest advantage - say, wine - and still procure its cloth from England in exchange for wine. Even if England had no absolute advantage, it would still have a comparative advantage in cloth with which it could engage profitably in foreign trade. By trade, both nations would wind up with more cloth and wine, and living standards would thus rise.
Thus, a nation with the great technological advantages of England can be better off producing more manufactured items for sale abroad in exchange for corn even from nations with lower levels of agricultural fertility than in England.
Even in circumstances where there is no government
interference in international trade - perfect globalization - such differences
would persist due to differences of domestic law and culture. Capital feels more
secure and workers feel more comfortable within familiar cultures, thus imposing
natural limits on the mobility of capital and labor. |
If a nation loses its advantage in its export commodities for some reason, it would have to exchange money - gold, in the 19th century - for its imports. This loss of gold would increase the domestic exchange value of gold - resulting in lower prices and labor costs - until sufficient comparative advantage should be reestablished so that it could again exchange goods for goods in international markets.
Ricardo goes into some detail about the commercial
mechanics of this process. In the country that gains gold, gold loses value
resulting in rising prices. This includes an increase in the prices for
subsistence commodities and thus an increase for the natural wages of labor. However, this
does not cause a reduction in profits as would an increase in corn costs
attributable to
domestic causes. When the supply of money increases, all prices rise together permitting domestic
producers of all products to maintain profit margins. |
|
Capital shifts are not exact. There is inevitably waste and error involved. Adjustments can overshoot the mark, requiring expensive withdrawals of capital later on. |
The problem is that these adjustments are never totally smooth or without loss, Ricardo acknowledges. There are individual inertia and government impediments to deal with. The costs of shifting capital from one use to another may be such that some producers will continue in production for some time at lower than standard profit rates. This can impact the profits of a whole industry. Capital shifts are not exact. There is inevitably waste and error involved. Adjustments can overshoot the mark, requiring expensive withdrawals of capital later on.
|
Gold flows between nations tend to be gradual and self correcting in normal times.
The noxious impacts of various mercantilist policies -
tariffs, quotas, trade prohibitions, trade subsidies - are extensively explained
by Ricardo. While in general agreement with Smith with respect to basic
principles, here, too, Ricardo expresses differences with respect to particular
impacts. |
|
In his opposition to the Corn Laws, Ricardo
emphasizes that the increased prices of protected grains may be of benefit to the farmers
- but only temporarily. Ultimately, market adjustments take these benefits away
from the farmers as capital flows in to take advantage of the higher profits.
Ultimately, all the benefits are transferred to the landlords. In the long run,
only the landlords benefit from agricultural protectionist policies. And there
is no benefit for the national interest from such benefits for landlords.
|
International monetary flows cause shifts in the terms
of trade. An influx or loss of gold is not without consequences even if self
limiting.
|
Thus, an increase in productivity that is relatively faster than in other nations is a double blessing. It not only increases wealth domestically, but it improves the terms of trade with an additional boost to productivity. As English industrial productivity advanced in the 19th century, it was able to procure more Portuguese wine for less of the labor embodied in English cloth.
|
|
The advent of paper money and negotiable
instruments brings various advantages but also permits serious abuses. The
Napoleonic Wars were financed by England with a vast expansion of paper notes
that would no longer be redeemed with gold or silver. Massive amounts of
government securities were issued that could be readily discounted.
|
Money:
& |
The value of monetary gold and silver
depends on the labor it takes to bring it into circulation. If gold is worth
15 times more than silver by weight, it is not because there is 15 times more
silver available, but because it takes 15 times more labor to bring the gold into
circulation. & |
Nevertheless, scarcity is still clearly a factor in value. Coins that have been worn or clipped do not lose value as long as they retain their relative scarcity. Paper money retains value almost entirely on the basis of scarcity alone.
The private banking system is part of a nation's monetary system. It is therefore the responsibility of the state to regulate banking. Unfortunately, governments, too, have a bad record at managing monetary systems. Thus, Ricardo asserts, the natural disciplines of a gold or silver standard seem like the best alternative.
|
|
The great advantages of paper for monetary
purposes are recognized by Ricardo. However, he also recognizes that the issuer labors under powerful temptations
to issue increasing amounts of paper money. Like Smith, he was quite familiar with the
periodic panics caused by undisciplined issuance of negotiable notes by the
private banks. Ricardo also recognized that a gold standard works only in normal
times. Financial panics would cause bank runs that could quickly
exhaust gold reserves.
Ricardo notes the temptations and political imperatives that lead to excess issuance of paper money, but he does not discuss the full consequences of chronic inflation.
|
Say's Law and Inadequate Demand
Say's law: The accumulation of capital cannot depress profits. |
There can't be too much capital accumulation
in a competitive market economy. In thus supporting the pertinent views of Jean
Babtiste Say, and opposing those of Smith, Ricardo again stresses the natural powers of
adjustment of the markets. Only higher natural wages will depress profits,
Ricardo insists. The accumulation of capital cannot do that. & |
The act of producing extra supply creates extra demand that tends to balance the system.
"There is no limit to demand," Ricardo emphasizes. When profits are too low to attract investment capital, there will be foreign investments. If profits on foreign investments are too low, money that otherwise would have been invested will be spent or saved, and interest rates will decline for consumer borrowing as well as investments, all of which will increase demand and profits sufficiently to restore balance.
Of course, Ricardo recognizes the glitches and delays in
the adjustment processes of real economic systems. He repeatedly brings them
into his discussions. In this chapter, he discusses state interference with
interest rates. Also, creative destruction and the redeployment of capital involve major
capital expenditures and losses.
|
Automation fears:
& |
Ricardo falls prey to automation
fears - a weakness that would afflict many economists right up to modern
times. It is possible, he believes, for improved productivity to render some
labor redundant. However, Ricardo at least is smart enough to view this as very unusual.
It is in no way some inevitable fate of "mature" capitalism. & |
Even though he recognizes that there is no limit to demand, he fails to appreciate the extent of the economic ability to produce more, improved, and new goods and services. Like so many intellectuals, since he is incapable of imagining what those new products and services might be, he is blind to them. His powers of calculating economic adjustments thus fail him in this instance.
However, he is not totally blind in this matter.
He notes that capital productivity gains proceed slowly, allowing time for
adjustments so that unemployment due to productivity gains never occurs. Every
increase in capital increases the demand for labor, even if at a diminishing
rate. |
The savings gap:
& |
The savings gap stupidity that would afflict Marx and Keynes and their followers is given indirect support by Ricardo. After the wealthy buy all the furniture and other luxury goods that they want, some of their income will go unspent - will be saved - leaving demand short of levels sufficient to maintain full employment. |
However, Ricardo is at least intelligent enough to realize that this insufficient demand at most could only occur in the short run - until market adjustments have brought matters back into balance. He thus rejects the notion of a chronic savings gap such as Marx and Keynes were stupid enough to believe in. Increased savings must lead to capital accumulation, Ricardo points out, and capital accumulation must result in increased demand and higher living standards. (Nevertheless, this segment of Ricardo's work is one of unconvincing and somewhat contradictory reasoning.) |
Taxes:
& |
The burdens of all taxes fall on capital or revenue.
Despite the vast expenses of the Napoleonic Wars, it is evident to Ricardo that
the revenues of Great Britain were sufficient to cover them without unduly
restricting public consumption or even preventing further capital accumulation.
The wealth of the nation and its revenues increased noticeably during the
two decades of the war. & |
Taxation methods are not viewed as critically as Smith views them, perhaps because of the experience during the wars. It is the rate of taxation rather than the particular methods used that is most important to Ricardo. No matter whether a tax be assessed against income or capital, it will burden just income if it can be paid from a similar deduction in expenses, and from capital to the extent that it is not.
Taxes must always be kept low enough to be paid from
revenues without reduction of capital. Taxes levied on capital asset
transactions - including estate taxes - obstruct the logical flows of capital
and reduce productivity. The result of taxation
is a decrease in productivity the net effects of which depend on any offsetting
productivity advantages bestowed by government activities - such as education, the
maintenance of law and order, the maintenance of the freedom of the seas, and the construction of useful
infrastructure. |
The substantial ability of the market economy to
adjust to various taxes limits their ultimate impacts, Ricardo repeatedly
stresses. He at various times notes the inherent loss of overall productivity
caused by taxation, but seldom includes that in his analysis of particular
taxes. He also on a couple of occasions mentions the affects of government
expenditure of tax revenues. This puts money back into circulation, but displaces
private consumption to some degree with government consumption. |
|
Business taxes are a cost of production that is passed on to buyers and ultimate consumers as a part of the cost of goods sold.
Income taxes are particularly obnoxious because of the reporting requirements and necessary enforcement procedures. |
Businesses don't pay taxes. They collect taxes. Business taxes are a cost of production that
is passed on to buyers and ultimate consumers as a part of the cost of goods
sold. The only businesses hurt are the marginal producers who are driven out of production by the increased
costs imposed by taxes. For those who survive,
business taxes cost little or nothing, since the reductions in the production of
failed businesses permit
a rise in prices sufficient to cover the costs of taxation.
|
A tax on monetary gold is the only commodity tax
that may not affect the broader economy. If there is less monetary gold, then
the remainder simply rises in value sufficiently to perform the same monetary
purposes. Ultimately, the people who pay out some of their gold to the tax
gatherer gain much of their loss back from the increase in value of the rest. |
|
The impacts of a tax on wages are exactly the same as a tax on profits. "Taxes on wages will raise wages, and therefore will diminish the rate of profits of stock."
Taxes on subsistence goods increase their price and thus increase the natural wages of subsistence labor. This depresses profit rates and capital accumulation, but the economic adjustments prevent the impacts from being as severe as presented by Smith. Taxes on discretionary items fall only on those that consume them. Luxury taxes have many additional advantages, but produce uncertain revenues. They may collapse demand - and collapse the producing industry - yielding little revenue.
Ricardo explains in detail why Smith and others were in error in their analyses of the extent of the impacts of taxes on wages and subsistence goods. Taxes reduce productivity and wealth in many ways - through a rise in costs to consumers and a general reduction in profit rates and capital accumulation. After the economy has had time to fully adjust, taxes on wages and subsistence goods actually have essentially the same impacts as most other taxes.
Tithes - percentage taxes on gross produce - are passed
on to consumers. Taxes on particular commodities reduce their production.
However, the economic impact is not the direct reduction in production, since
capital is simply redirected elsewhere. The impact is in this distortion -
shifting production and consumption to less efficient uses and to channels
deemed less desirable by the public. |
|
With respect to rent taxes, Ricardo has some
disagreements with Smith. He denigrates the landlord interest almost as much as
does Smith, and agrees that a tax on rent is peculiarly attractive since its impact
falls only on the landlord - an unproductive class of people. |
War debts:
& |
The great war debts of the Napoleonic Wars
are a primary concern of Ricardo. He sets forth all the well known impacts of
these war debts. Ricardo concludes that it would be best if these debts were
paid off as quickly as possible - even at the expense of a one time reduction in
capital. After all, what would happen if the debt burden were still in existence
when the next war - or the next unexpected major emergency - came along.? & |
Similar worries had occupied Adam Smith, concerning the war debts of the 18th century wars. The two great worldwide conflicts that included the French and Indian War and the American Revolution in North America left debts of about 170£ million. Yet, when the Napoleonic Wars came along, they dwarfed all the previous wars in financial costs and debt burdens assumed, leaving debts of almost 500£ million. However, Ricardo notes that England was able to cope - and even to finance its allies and to expand its economic wealth.
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2004 Dan Blatt