NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOKS
available at Amazon in
Hard cover, soft cover, ebook
Trade War "Understanding the Great
Depression Explaining the Great Depression, its Trade War, and failures of "New" Keynesian interest rate suppression policy without ideological clap trap, theory confirmation bias or political spin. |
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 3, No. 4, 4/1/01.
Cassandra ignored: |
There was no mystery about the causes of the
Great Depression Crash of 1929. Nor was there any mystery about the forces
that thereafter prevented recovery and caused the decade-long
economic disaster of the Great Depression. ? |
Economists - starting with John Maynard Keynes as
early as 1919 - had written extensively about the weaknesses and
dangers of government policies that ultimately were among the major
blunders that brought
on the Great Depression. Of course, the usual "authoritative"
governmental and private voices determinedly ignored these warnings
and dominated press coverage of the debate. However, by the beginning
of 1931, even the press was forced to recognize the blatant stupidity
of these "authoritative voices," and began providing
extensive coverage of those pointing an accusing finger at government policies as the causes of the economic debacle. ? See the seven FUTURECASTS "Great Depression Chronology" articles, taken primarily from contemporary accounts. |
The Great Deception:
? |
Nevertheless, the various enemies of capitalism and
advocates of egalitarian, collectivist and/or command economy economic policy approaches
viewed the Great Depression as a wonderful opportunity to attack
capitalism and further their various causes. They proceeded to
use the Great Depression - successfully - to discredit capitalism
in whole or in part - to cast blame on capitalism for the Great
Depression - and to offer their own approaches as substitutes
for - or the means to save - capitalism. ? |
Advocacy scholars have filled whole library shelves with the most incredible stupidity in their efforts to convince the American people to abandon free markets in favor of socialist, "industrial policy," and entitlement welfare state alternatives. |
A combination of widespread complicity and ignorance
in intellectual and academic circles facilitated these efforts.
John Maynard Keynes and his legion of followers were - and remain
- especially complicit. Advocacy scholars like John Kenneth Galbraith
and Lester C. Thurow (Paul Krugman calls them "policy entrepreneurs")
filled whole library shelves with the most incredible stupidity
in their efforts to convince the American people to abandon free
markets in favor of socialist, "industrial policy," or entitlement welfare state alternatives that uniformly proved disastrous
whenever and wherever in the world they were tried. Advocacy
scholars routinely cited the Great Depression as a primary example
of the weaknesses and instability of capitalism that required resort to their
alternative policies. See, Modern Advocacy Scholars. ? The result was that a mythology concerning the causes and cures of the Great Depression became one of its most lasting - and dangerous - legacies. FDR and most of the New Deal policy makers accepted several of these myths. These beliefs explain initial New Deal disinterest in the restoration of world trade - and its resort instead to monetary inflation, deficit spending, cartel-like price and wage fixing policies, and other command economy policies - that condemned the nation to five more years of Depression. ? For an example of the distortions still being caused by these myths in serious scholarship, see, David Kennedy, "Freedom from Fear" (I), Economic Great Depression, a seriously flawed Pulitzer prize winning volume of the Oxford History of the U.S. ? |
The causes of the Great Depression were cumulative and complex. Static analysis of this issue is inherently incompetent. |
Herein, FUTURECASTS deals with seven of these myths
- some totally fallacious and others misleading half-truths - six of which concern causes of, and one the cure for, the Great
Depression. Also presented are some of the anomalies of the Crash, a
presentation of the FUTURECASTS view of the complex factors involved in the
Great Depression collapse and failure to recover, a summary of basic indisputable facts,
and a graphic presentation
of contemporary economic indicators and Crash facts through 1930. ? The cumulative and complex interactions of these events are stressed. Indeed, they cannot be overemphasized. Static analysis of this issue is inherently incompetent. ? No single factor provides an adequate explanation for the Great Depression. This was not an "inventory" problem - as in 1921. It was not caused by austerity measures required to get inflation under control - as in 1980. There were no major banking failures until more than a year after the Crash of '29. ? The complex mix of governmental policy stupidities in the U.S. and internationally - and the cumulative mix of their manifold economic impacts building up throughout the 1920s - made the world's capitalist system vulnerable to Depression and thereafter prevented recovery. The ordinary economic problems that tend to accumulate during prosperous times, and the many triggering factors that played temporary roles in initiating the '29 Crash, are also herein set forth. |
|
The Great Depression - the decade-long
economic disaster of the 1930s - shook confidence in the stability
of capitalist economic systems. It apparently validated one of
the many stupidities of Karl Marx - the expectation of ultimate
capitalist instability and collapse. ? |
|
It was not the stock market crash and
the economic reversal - as bad as they were - that shook confidence
in the system. Capitalism had suffered periodic panics and depressions
throughout the 19th century, and even suffered several reversals
in the generally prosperous decade after WW-I. In an imperfect
world - with periodic unexpected crises and imperfect economic policies and
practices, both governmental and private - such reversals were
understandable. They were even viewed as part of the process
by which capitalist market mechanisms forced needed correction of errors. ? There was no lack of understanding of the broad weaknesses of the economic policies of the 1920s. Also, the overextended nature of the financial situation in the fall of 1929 was notorious despite official efforts to gloss over the problems. ? |
|
But the automatic corrective powers of the markets
failed this time. Massive price and policy adjustments were
ruthlessly forced on a typically reluctant world - but without
apparent affect. Unlike past depressions, no amount of policy
reversals or liquidation of overextended positions was enough
to establish new equilibrium points, restore stability and create
the conditions for recovery. ? It was this failure to recover that was the critical difference for the Great Depression. This is what seemed to validate the Marxist myth. ? |
|
Marx wrote that the capitalist drive
to invest and expand production was so powerful that it would
inevitably push supply beyond demand, cause profits to
plummet and capital to collapse, bringing on a crisis (like the
Great Depression) that would end the capitalist system. ? So potent was this myth - so traumatic was the Great Depression - that for decades after WW II, people still expected a renewal of depression and conducted their lives accordingly. Many people - often despite great personal prosperity - lived austere lives, saved every dime they could, made only the most conservative investments, some even avoiding the purchase of a home, in expectation of a renewal of depression. ? |
|
John Maynard Keynes accepted much of
the Marxist stupidity, including the myth of the inherent instability
of capitalism. He predicted that a 20 year period of prosperity
would result in such a flow of investment and expansion of supply
that profits would be critically squeezed. This would force the
government to take possession of all major productive assets
so that it could prevent economic collapse and run the assets
for public benefit. ? His followers, like Prof. Paul A. Samuelson, author of the leading college economics textbook during the 1950s and 1960s, still fretted about this mythological instability decades later. Samuelson wrote that the arrival of the computer and the development of "automation" could initiate the feared inherent instability. ? |
|
Of course, this was always obvious nonsense.
Increases in productivity always permit capitalist systems to
produce more and newer and better goods and services - at lower prices - than before. As long as the economy retains sufficient
capitalist flexibility, productivity increases always increase
demand and create more and better paying jobs. Creative destruction
is a vital part of this process - forcing the demise of outmoded,
poorly managed and poorly placed facilities - so that the feared accumulation of excess productive assets never occurs. ? Advances such as that made possible by computers have always created more jobs than they destroy. In fact, the computer has proven itself the champion job-creating technology of all time - world wide - even surpassing the automobile. ? That academics and government officials never have any clue as to what the new or improved goods and services will be - or which productive assets should be permitted to die and which should be permitted to expand - is just one more explanation of the need for economic freedom and the impossibility of successful government "industrial policy," centralized socialist or other command economy approaches. |
|
The Keynesian explanation for the business
cycle and the initiation of depression is based on his savings
gap (his "liquidity preference") fallacy. Keynes theorized
that, during prosperity, savings expand faster than investment
opportunities, thus ultimately resulting in insufficient demand
to sustain prosperity. ? |
In fact, as prosperity increases in free market capitalist nations, prosperous people rely increasingly on their asset wealth for reserve purposes, and need less savings. |
Unfortunately, reality perversely failed
to conform to Keynesian expectations. Savings - which had
increased substantially in good years and in bad for two decades
- actually declined in the last year before the '29 Crash. Not
only did the amount of savings decline, there was actually a
decline of more than 500,000 in the number of accounts on the
books of the savings banks. Savings accounts had been increasing
by 3 million to 5 million per year, in good years and bad, since
WW-I. Indeed, before the '29 Crash, banks had insufficient savings
with which to meet all investment needs, as proven by the rising
interest rates. ? Current prosperity has since been accompanied by declining savings rates instead of rising savings rates - which gives economists something else to worry about. In fact, as prosperity increases in free market capitalist nations, prosperous people rely increasingly on their asset wealth for reserve purposes, and need less savings. It is in developing countries and nations like Japan that have government directed financial systems that the highest savings rates are found. ? Where there are modern banking systems and money markets, savings do not lie idle in bank vaults, or get stuffed uselessly into mattresses, until well after depressions begin and banks begin to fail. During prosperous times, money markets facilitate the useful employment of all savings deposits. ? Current efforts to blame income disparities also fail, for similar reasons. The surge in income of the top 20% in 1929 - and today - did not and has not resulted in increased savings rates and insufficient demand. Indeed, Keynesians should today be advocating even greater income disparities - as a cure for the declining savings rates that they currently find so worrisome. ? If the current "politically correct" myth that income disparity was a cause of the Great Depression is correct, then we should expect this first decade of the 21st century to be another Great Depression decade. Disparities in 1999 were much greater than in 1929. While some period of recession is likely during this decade - as FUTURECASTS has long asserted - a return to anything like the Great Depression is definitely not in the cards. |
? |
Federal Reserve Board monetary tightness
in the first three quarters of 1929 - in response to the speculative
excesses of that period - has also drawn criticism from Keynesians - and
more recently from monetarist followers of Milton Friedman and Allan Meltzer
- and fails similarly because of the perverse failure of reality
to conform to this theory. ? |
As the Great Depression deepened, there was an adverse credit shift -- a rapid decline in the number of individuals and businesses - and governments - that had the credit to borrow at the low interest rates. Even more important, there was a rapid decline in the profitable opportunities that could justify the incurrence of debt. |
Interest rates did move higher in
the first seven months of 1929. Short term "call" rates
were at or above 15% at times during March, April, May
and July of 1929. However, they had already dropped to 10% and below by the end of August, 1929. There were substantial
interest rate cuts in the first week of October and thereafter,
driving rates to 7% and below, weeks before the actual
Crash.
Indeed, interest rates declined to the lowest
levels since the summer of 1928. By the middle of November, 1929,
basic short term interest rates had declined to 5% and
below. During the first half of 1930 it was readily noticeable to the Fed
and many others that money in circulation was declining due to a lack of
borrowing demand rather than any shortage of available funds.
Of course, abundant liquidity and low interest rates did not mean "easy money." As the Great Depression deepened, there was an adverse credit shift -- a rapid decline in the number of individuals and businesses - and governments - that had the credit to borrow at the low interest rates. Even more important, there was a rapid decline in the profitable opportunities that could justify the incurrence of debt. |
? |
Criticism of British efforts to restore
the gold standard after WW-I at rates that left the pound
sterling grossly overvalued,
is similar to the tight money criticism, and proves similarly
inadequate as an explanation of the Great Depression. For several
years before the Great Depression, economists criticized the
over valuation of the pound and warned that this would
force economic contraction until domestic prices and wages were
driven down far enough to justify those valuations. ? |
|
This was undoubtedly true, and is exactly
what happened in England in the mid 1920s. England tried to restore
the pound sterling at an unrealistically high value - $4.86 per
pound sterling - although France more realistically pegged the
franc at just 20% of its pre WW-I value. Moreover, since
the British pound was then the world's premier reserve currency,
turbulence in the pound had broad significance well beyond Great
Britain and its Empire. ? However, this does not explain the Great Depression. An overvalued pound should have helped other European nations - at least until the Great Depression hit England. It thus does not explain why Germany and almost all other European nations other than France and the Scandinavian nations fell into depression before England - and why recovery failed even after England's domestic and export prices were driven down well beyond levels that should have corrected any of the imbalances in foreign trade caused by the excessive currency valuations. ? It also does not take into account the role of U.S. policies in the breakdown of the gold standard. The Federal Reserve System monetary sterilization policies undermined the adjustment mechanisms of the gold standard, and the U.S. trade war levels of tariffs overburdened it. See, Friedman & Schwartz, "Monetary History of U.S.(1867-1960), Part II, "Roaring Twenties Boom - Great Depression Bust (1921-1933)", at segment on "Sterilization of Gold;" and Meltzer, "History of Federal Reserve (1913-1951)," Part II, "The Engine of Deflation (1923-1933)," at section F) "The Search for an Administered Alternative." ? The gold standard did not fail. The protectionist trade war policies of the United States government and its sterilization of gold inflows critically obstructed the functioning of the gold standard and played a major role in the collapse of international markets and the onset and continuation of the Great Depression. |
? |
The psychological explanation for the
Great Depression asserts that the "irrational optimism"
of the boom was replaced by "irrational pessimism"
during the Crash. The stock markets were certainly overoptimistic
before the Crash of '29, maintaining their high levels for weeks
in the face of an incoming tide of worsening financial news.
They finally gave way after some critical economic activities
began to decline, providing irrefutable evidence of imminent
economic decline. ? |
|
Indeed, optimism is the prevailing nature
of financial markets. Only optimists play the market. Only optimists
risk what they have in the hope of receiving adequate compensation
for their investment in the uncertain future. ? In fact, the market continued to behave optimistically - continued to expect and to discount future recovery - for at least one year after the Crash. The market did not go straight down. It repeatedly rebounded vigorously at every opportunity, resuming the decline each time - but only after irrefutable evidence that the economic decline was continuing and that economic recovery was not in sight. ? Dividend yields were an attractive form of return on investment in those days before high marginal tax rates. Yield rates, even though based on previous year earnings - which were clearly significantly higher than those expected immediately thereafter - did not indicate that the market had become pessimistic - that the market had lost hope of impending recovery - until the end of 1930. Indeed, it wasn't until the last half of 1931 that yield rates rose high enough to indicate that the market had begun to discount further decline. ? By that time, it was irrational not to be pessimistic. |
|
The devastating financial losses suffered
in the '29 Crash provides us with the final - and most widespread - false explanation for the Great Depression. ? |
|
This argument is especially attractive because
of its simplicity and directness. It appears to be simple cause
and effect. First came the speculative boom. Then came the inevitable
bust. Then came the business Depression. ? The New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) lost over one-third of its value from its high of about $90.5 billion on September 19, 1929, to its low of about $60 billion after the October, 1929, Crash. By November 13, 1929, it had fallen to about $48 billion - nearly a 50% drop in less than two months. There were similar declines on the smaller stock markets both within the United States and abroad., ? The Keynesians are particularly attracted to this argument because it appears to justify the government intervention by means of budgetary deficits and monetary expansion that the Keynesians favor. Even at this late date, many Keynesian economists continue to offer this simple - and simplistic - explanation for the Great Depression. ? |
|
To repeat, the stock markets did not go
straight down. If you are going to blame financial losses
from the '29 Crash for the Great Depression, then you must explain
why the substantial financial gains of the market rebounds in
November and December of 1929 and in the spring of 1930 - accompanied
by gains from the bond markets which remained strong into June
of 1930 - failed to stimulate recovery. ? Bond financing and refinancing surged in the early months of 1930 as public and private entities took advantage of the lower rates to lower their financing costs. ? |
|
By April 10, 1930, the NYSE had rebounded
to recover about 73% of its losses. It had surged about
$30 billion, a gain of about 65%, in just five months,
and stood at less than $12 billion below its all time high - a
loss of only about 12%. ? Moreover, gains in the bond markets undoubtedly further cut total losses from securities markets for that period. |
G) Facts about the Crash of 1929
|
? |
Imports and exports showed the most
severe and inexorable decline. They began to tail off before
the summer of 1929. By the first quarter of 1930, they were running
at about 23% below previous year levels - about half due
to declining prices and half to declining volume. The passage
of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff on June 17, 1930, and the retaliatory
tariff increases all around the world, accelerated the decline.
It would continue at multiple double digit rates well into 1933.
Exports for the last half of 1932 ran 82% below those
of 1929. ? |
|
The collapse of international markets in copper,
silver, textiles and agricultural commodities clearly undermined
the promising spring, 1930, business revival. Particularly damaging
were the approximately 50% declines in wheat and auto exports. Both
of these declines had begun before the autumn of 1929. (See "The
trade war," below.) ? Automotive exports in the first quarter of 1930 fell 46% below 1929 levels. Autos had been dependent on exports for as much as 20% of sales. The precipitous drop in automotive exports cost the industry about 40,000 units per month in that first quarter of 1930, when economic recovery had its best chance. ? The sudden and disappointing decline in automotive exports and sales in the spring of 1929 was one of the first major signs of economic trouble. This resulted in large inventories that weren't worked down until the winter after the Crash. This resulted in immediate substantial cuts in the production of autos and, by September, 1929, in steel and other associated industries as well. ? During the first quarter of 1930, and in the subsequent recovery periods of the next three years, almost all financial and economic elements had periods of recovery - except for exports and imports. ? Depressed business conditions increasingly affected the domestic economy as one sector after another began to decline, well before the April 10, 1930 stock market recovery high. The value of real estate was dropping sharply, devastating second mortgages and the small rural banks that held them. Bankruptcies were running at or near record levels. Railroad car loadings - an especially important economic indicator in those days - were running at seven year lows - indicating that real problems remained and were growing in the "real" economy. ? It is thus not in the securities markets, but here in the "real" economy - and in the political policies that affected the "real" economy - that one must look for the causes of the Great Depression and the reasons why market adjustments were unable to restore the conditions needed for recovery. |
|
Synergy at its worst:
? |
Obviously, it required a combination of
many powerful causes to undermine the inherently stable and
incredibly resilient capitalist economic system, and enmesh the world in
the Great Depression. No theory that emphasizes just one or two of these
factors - or that fails to consider the massive synergistic impacts of
all of them functioning together - is going to be able to provide a
valid understanding of these events. There is simply no easy one dimensional answer or theory
that will suffice. ? Moreover, all of the economic causes were quickly eliminated by vigorous market adjustments, but the political causes took years and even more than a decade to remove, and new political policy blunders were added at various points during the decade. ? |
All of the economic causes were quickly eliminated by vigorous market adjustments, but the political causes took years to remove - and new political policy blunders were added.
|
The political blunders stayed stubbornly in place - and incredibly
were periodically even made worse and compounded with additional policy
blunders - until economic systems collapsed and governments themselves
were smashed or politically replaced - and the world descended into the
abyss of WW-II.. ? Of these primary political causes, the trade war restraint and subsidy policies remained and grew substantially worse even as all the other causes - major and minor - economic and political - ran their course, were liquidated, or otherwise came to an end. The trade war restraint and subsidy policies were joined by New Deal cartel-like price and wage fixing policies and other command economy policies that provided new political policy blunders that became additional weighty factors preventing economic recovery. ? To repeat, there was no mystery about the causes of the Great Depression. By the beginning of 1931, articles in the contemporary financial press covered them all. Unfortunately, most investors ignored them until the '29 Crash and - more importantly and incredibly - most of the politicians and bureaucrats in Washington, D.C., determinedly ignored them even after the '29 Crash. ? |
For purposes of analysis, FUTURECASTS divides these causes into three groups.
|
Fundamental causes: |
World War I has to be the starting point
for any analysis of the Great Depression. Indeed, many contemporary
commentators called the Great Depression "The Last Battle
of the Great War." ? |
|
There were many physical economic distortions
caused by the conflict, as one would expect from any great war.
However, by 1929, only the massive surplus agricultural capacity - especially
in the United States - remained. Moreover, by 1928, worldwide trade war
protectionist and subsidy policies had extended this problem worldwide. ? American farmers substantially increased production to feed Europe during the war, but they did not decrease production after the war. The federal government provided an agricultural exemption from the antitrust laws in 1922, and encouraged the formation of agricultural cooperatives that shielded farmers from market pressures that would have forced reductions in agricultural production. This proved to be a very imperfect shield for the smaller and less efficient producers but, more importantly, encouraged further expansion of the larger and most efficient producers. ? Farm income ran more than 50% above prosperous pre WW-I levels from 1924 through 1928. There was a rapid mechanization of farming methods in the 1920s that greatly increased productivity. Wheat acreage actually peaked as late as 1927. Annual wheat exports ran substantially above 200 million bushels during the four years before 1929 from a crop that averaged above 820 million bushels. Despite the excess capacity and the continuous "creative destruction" of inefficient small farms, this was hardly a picture of widespread agricultural distress. ? However, the excess capacity problem became critical after the record U.S. and worldwide wheat crops of 1928 - which left huge surplus carryovers and threatened agricultural commodity prices. In 1930, the trade war destroyed the European market for U.S. and Canadian wheat. Incredibly, U.S. Government subsidization policies were instituted in the summer of 1929, and continued even after the '29 Crash, resulting in disastrously huge crops in 1930 and 1931. These were almost as large as the 1928 record crop -- they were produced during a period when exports had been cut more than in half -- and they were priced out of vital export markets by the price supports. ? |
War debts: |
There were also many financial burdens
as a result of the war, as the combatants borrowed heavily to
finance their military efforts. ? War debts - both domestic and foreign - are an especially heavy financial burden since they finance only consumption. Unlike debts that finance investments that, hopefully, provide more than the wherewithal needed to meet debt servicing costs, war debts are for "consumption" of wartime goods and services, and are a leaden financial weight on economic systems. ? |
|
The Treaty of Versailles that ended the
war imposed vindictive terms on the losers. The widespread public
emotions that led to this result were certainly understandable - but the
vindictive peace treaty was a catastrophic policy blunder. See, MacMillan,
"Paris 1919, Part I,
"The Reordering of Europe," and Part
II, "The Far East, the Middle East, and the Treaty of Versailles," ? Germany's reparations obligations were massive and - in combination with the trade war that followed WW-I - resulted in the destruction of the German economy. Germany was the third most important customer for American exports, and was even more important as a customer for European nations. See, Keynes, "The Economic Consequences of the Peace." ? |
? |
The trade war began soon after WW-I. It involved high tariffs, quotas, licensing requirements,
currency restrictions and other restraints on international trade,
along with domestic trade restraints and subsidy and price support programs.
It also involved the failure of the Federal Reserve System and French
monetary authorities to operate in accordance with gold standard rules.
Instead of using gold, they hoarded it and drained it from the international
system.
Tariffs and other limits on imports were deemed
necessary to assure maximum self sufficiency in preparation for
"the next round" of great European wars. There were
no illusions in Europe about "The Great War" being
the last big European war. By generally undermining economic
stability and preventing recovery in Germany and elsewhere in Europe, trade war restrictions
proved to be an important part of a self-fulfilling prophesy. |
The trade war impact on market prices was dramatic. This
multiplied its impact on affected economic segments and the broader
economy. When Federal Farm
Board price supports were overwhelmed, agricultural commodity prices sunk like stones. Agriculture Department farm income figures show the impact -
dropping from $12 billion in 1929 to $9 1/3 billion, $7 billion, and $5 1/4
billion in 1932, despite periodic Farm Board efforts to support prices. ? The automobile industry was similarly impacted, as pointed out above. The collapse of the vast agricultural sector had an immediate impact on domestic auto sales, housing and rural real estate - the "big ticket" consumer items - critically undermining the promising spring, 1930, business revival. |
|
|
When evaluating the impact of these
fundamental causes, it cannot be emphasized too much that their
impact was cumulative. Even for the United States, it
was not limited to just the 8% of the economy consisting
of foreign trade. ? Moreover, "war" implies offense as well as defense. Trade wars include not just "defense" against imports by such methods as tariffs, quotas, licensing requirements, discriminatory regulation, currency exchange controls, etc., but also "offense" that encourages domestic production of goods in international commerce by such methods as subsidies, price and wage fixing, credit allocations, special tax breaks, etc. Those who reject the trade war as a primary cause of the Great Depression routinely ignore the offensive side of the battle. ? Moreover, their impact was synergistic. The noxious impacts of trade war policies were compounded by the WW-I financial obligations and the steadily increasing levels of other forms of indebtedness. These impacts grew in intensity during the course of the decade after WW-I until protected industries developed gross overcapacity and huge surplus carryovers - the economies of many foreign nations were destroyed - export markets were decimated - prices on international commodity markets collapsed - and vast American agricultural and mining sectors were devastated - with dire consequences for the rest of the economy. See "K) Cumulative Impacts," below |
|
Economic cause and effect, by its nature,
is a never ending phenomenon. Intermediate economic impacts become
themselves the causes of further developments. ? |
The stock market was repeatedly driven down by commodity price declines, and reductions in railroad car loadings and steel production.
|
The list of intermediate effects
is divided into two groups. There are those that
arose as a result of worldwide economic events prior to the
'29 Crash and those that arose after the '29 Crash from worsening
economic and financial conditions and from the '29 Crash, itself. ? It is clear from this list that the '29 Crash itself was primarily the messenger of bad economic news, and as such its impact was primarily (but of course not entirely) as an expediter of reactions to the rapidly deteriorating economic and financial conditions. It was not itself a primary precipitator of events, but was a powerful but temporary intermediate force. ? When deteriorating economic conditions forced resumption of the stock market decline in April, 1930, that too became a powerful intermediate factor in the Great Depression. However, market breaks always were driven by disappointing business developments that accumulated to undeniable proportions prior to the market declines. All stock market declines were thus rationally explained by those disappointing economic developments. ? Between September, 1929, and the end of 1930, stock market declines were initiated predominantly by commodity price declines, reductions in railroad car loadings, and especially reductions in steel production, which slowly forced a shift in market sentiment from the discounting of future growth to the discounting of no growth and, in 1931, to the discounting of continued decline. ? |
Railroad car loadings - a preeminent economic indicator in those days - joined the list of declining business segments during the week before the '29 Crash. |
Intermediate effects prior to the '29 Crash:
|
European wheat acreage had expanded substantially behind protective tariffs, and provided Europe with a bumper crop that more than fulfilled all European needs for 1930. This undermined the entire agricultural segment of the U.S. economy and changed its economic world. |
Intermediate and triggering effects after the '29 Crash:
|
Triggering events of the '29 Crash:
? |
Most impressive about this next list, especially
given the existence of all the major economic and financial weaknesses
set forth in the prior lists, is the volume of threatening developments
that had to accumulate before the stock market crashed.
|
These many weaknesses and disruptions certainly indicated that the coming turn in the business cycle - the next depression - would be a bad one. The markets quickly and ruthlessly eliminated all of the economic factors, but they would have to smash governments and bring on WW-II before they could force the elimination of the worst of the political policy blunders that caused the Great Depression.
The futility of deficit spending, monetary expansion, and cartel-like price and wage fixing and other command economy policies:
That the New Deal was complicit in the duration and severity of the Great Depression today looks quite unexceptional - and even obvious. |
Ultimately, the Great Depression ended - without the help of socialist
or command economy or Keynesian policies. Indeed,
substantial levels of deficit spending and monetary expansion,
and a host of government economic activities, including price and wage maintenance schemes and blatant make work projects, notoriously
failed to stimulate economic recovery, and actually obviously made matters
much worse than they otherwise would have been. ? Recent scholarly analysis by UCLA economists Lee E. Ohanian and Harold L. Cole attributes as much as 60% of the failure of recovery during the New Deal period to New Deal cartel-like price and wage fixing policies. ? Casting blame on the New Deal for condemning the nation and the world to many years of additional Depression would have been ideological anathema just a few decades ago. However, there has since been the obvious failure worldwide of the great and disastrous command economy and socialist experiments which devastated the lives of billions of people during the 20th century. ? The proposition that the New Deal was complicit in the duration and severity of the Great Depression today looks quite unexceptional - and even obvious. The only quibble is the degree to which each major group of policy blunders - such as continued trade war restraints and subsidization policies, cartel-like price and wage fixing policies, and other command economy policies - contributed to the ongoing disaster. ? |
|
Substantial recovery did not really begin
until 1939. Not until the U.S. started to fill its Armed Forces with
12 million young men and women did the unemployment problem disappear. ? Thus, the conventional wisdom was that only WW-II saved the world from the Great Depression. Socialists support this view because it appears to demonstrate the utility of and need for large scale government employment. Keynesians support this view because it appears to indicate that we just didn't run large enough deficits in the 1930s or expand the money supply quite enough to overcome the substantial problems caused by the Great Depression. ? For the critics of capitalism, government programs are simply never quite big enough - and never have quite enough money to spend - to achieve the promised results. ? |
|
To repeat - every one of the causes
listed above - including the fundamental causes, intermediate
causes, and triggering causes - had run its course, been liquidated,
or otherwise been brought to an end, by the summer of 1933 --
except for the trade war -- which had vastly increased its
strangle hold on world trade since the enactment of the Smoot-Hawley
Tariff. ? WW-II was not needed for recovery. All that was needed was the ending of the trade war. The elimination of protectionist tariffs and other barriers to trade, an end to subsidy programs and other restraints on domestic competition, and the restoration of world trade, was required to remove this one last oppressive obstacle to recovery. To the extent that WW-II provided an excuse and opportunity for the elimination of protectionist trade barriers, it did contribute to the end of the Great Depression and the assurance of economic prosperity after the war. ? The Roosevelt administration didn't start to poke some holes in trade war tariffs and other restrictions until 1935, when it began to negotiate bilateral reciprocal trade agreements. It was not until 1938, however, that this effort reached substantial proportions. Even then, the tariff reductions were relatively small. Not until the start of WW-II in September, 1939, did foreign trade begin to recover. ? The start of WW-II in Europe saved the Roosevelt presidency by opening the door to U.S. trade. The embattled European nations began large scale purchases of war materials from the U.S., and U.S. exporters began to service markets that European suppliers could no longer accommodate. ? After WW-II, the U.S. was in a dominating financial position, and could lead the world towards trade liberalization and the end of the trade war. ? |
|
John Maynard Keynes and his followers - to their great
credit - played major roles in the political and
diplomatic activities that ended the trade war. However, even then, their
grand schemes for international stabilization efforts quickly proved
impractical and were displaced by a simple system based on the dollar and
pound as key reserve currencies. ? The much feared and widely expected return of depression conditions after WW-II became just one more of the numerous occasions during which reality perversely refused to comply with the expectations of Marxists, socialists - and Keynesians. |
Momentum:
? |
That impacts of economic policies are
cumulative is so obvious that FUTURECASTS shouldn't have to explain
it. Nevertheless, economic propagandists frequently ignore cumulative
impacts as part of their ongoing efforts to distort economic reality, and
economic theorists often disregard them because they create vast
complications that are difficult and often impossible to deal with as
matters of theory - and especially as matters of econometric analysis. This requires a response. ? |
The '29 Crash and the Great Depression were the cumulative result of WW I and a decade of gross stupidity by government policy makers. |
The American economy is a battleship,
not a row boat. It cannot be turned on a dime. ? The real causes of the '29 Crash and the Great Depression run back to WW-I and the economic policies of the entire decade after the war. ? These policies were Republican policies - although they were maintained and even made worse by the New Deal Democrats. However, the Wilson administration had provided one of the few periods of relatively free trade in the nation's history and the Democrats did oppose the tariffs. The public has since rightly punished the Republican party for these huge transgressions by decisively ending their post Civil War reign as the nation's majority party and relegating them to minority status until the end of the 20th century. ? The '29 Crash was not the cause of the Great Depression. Indeed, securities market declines actually played just a minor role among the many cyclical factors driving the Great Depression to ever deeper depths. ? |
Inflationary problems of the 1970s and the depression of 1980 - 1982 were the cumulative results of two decades of inflationary policies. |
A similar analysis applies to many other
major economic developments since the Great Depression. The dozen
turbulent years after 1970 - the devaluation of the dollar - the
price inflation - the vicious swings of the business cycle - the
stagflation and "malaise" - the depression of 1980-1982 - and
even the below par economic performance of the next dozen years - were not
caused or initiated by the oil embargoes and oil price spikes of the
1970s. The oil embargoes, dollar devaluation, and price inflation problems
of the 1970s, and the subsequent depression, were caused by two decades of
government economic policy stupidity and the adoption of Keynesian
policies. ? The inflationary forces that caused the economic problems of the 1970s were initiated in the 1950s and massively accelerated by the inflationary policies pursued in the 1960s. Price inflation could be repressed only so long as the huge hoard of gold held by the U.S. after WW-II could sustain the value of the dollar. Inflationary policies provide pleasant results until they undermine the value of the currency, after which the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment collapses, and inflation causes unemployment and economic decline. ? |
Our current prosperity was made possible by policies adopted in the 1980s. |
A similar analysis applies to the
economic prosperity of the 1990s. This was sustained and encouraged by
beneficial economic policies during the Clinton administration and
Republican control of Congress after 1994, but the
foundations were put in place by the strengthening of the dollar and the
reduction of inflationary pressures under Republican administrations
during the prior decade. ? |
The cumulative impact of economic policy:
? |
It is a characteristic of many
stupid economic policies - both private and governmental - that their negative impacts cumulate over
time. This is typical of inflation, noxious tax incentives, socialist
schemes, command economy arrangements - and the continuous assumption of
large debts for purposes of consumption rather than for investment
purposes - and protectionist trade restraints and subsidy policies. ? |
Price support schemes in the major agricultural commodities, and in copper, rubber, steel and silver collapsed as a result of gross overcapacity and the surpluses they produced.
Hoards of agricultural workers lacking non agricultural skills were suddenly thrown into unemployment at a time when there was no employment to be had.
The collapse of agriculture also undermined agricultural implements, shipping, various real estate sectors, and rural banks.
The trade war held down U.S. international trade to perhaps as little as 50% of what it would have been, with obvious implications for agriculture and related economic segments. |
The cumulative effects of the heavy WW-I
financial obligations and the trade war of the 1920s slowly undermined the
economies of one nation after another - and then hindered and often
prevented recovery. As one nation after another declined, American
investors lost large sums from the collapse of the affected foreign bonds,
and important American exporters lost valuable markets.
And this time, wheat was not alone. Exports of cotton bales and cotton textiles
were similarly important and similarly affected by the collapse
of international markets - especially after the collapse of silver
prices in the spring of 1930 and the resulting sharp devaluations
of currencies denominated in silver all around the world. By the second half
of 1930, all world markets for agricultural and industrial commodities
were in a state of collapse |
Substantial outcome determinative facts:
? |
Any economic theory of business cycles in general - or of the Great Depression in particular - must include and be able to explain all the substantial outcome determinative facts of the economic events of 1929 and 1930. The facts in the subsequent years of economic decline are set forth in Debate begins (1931), and in the Collapse of international finance (1931), and in the Collapse of WW-I financial obligations (1932), and in the Collapse of governments (1932). |
Both the Crash of '29 and the Great Depression itself were clearly the result of disappointing business conditions caused by policy blunders - indeed, gross policy stupidities - of governments in the U.S. and around the world. |
The chronology of events in the months just before "The Crash of '29," and in the Rebound from the Crash of '29 during the early months of 1930, and in "The collapse of agriculture (1930)," thereafter, provides evidence that is both clear and convincing - and frequently beyond any reasonable doubt - that:
Both the Crash of 1929 and the Great Depression itself were clearly the result of disappointing business conditions caused by policy blunders - indeed, gross policy stupidities - of governments all around the world - but with the government of the U.S. especially complicit. |
Total NYSE values - 50 stock index yields - Steel production (U.S. Steel and Bethlehem Steel production generally ran somewhat higher) - Exports
$$$$$ = Total NYSE values as of first day of
month. ____> = Movement highs or lows. [Dividend Yield of NY Times 50 stock index] ###### = Steel production, % of capacity. ? |
Exports for
quarter, |
7/1/29 - Summer Boom $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($77.2 billion) [Yield - 3.37%] ################################################ (96%) ? Poor crops abroad spur recovery of agricultural commodities - economy booming - commodities and securities markets recover from short sharp May decline - call rate hits 15%. ? 8/1/29 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($84.2 billion) [Yield - 3.25%] ################################################ (95%) ? Exports, auto production, construction fall - brokers loans rise sharply - call rate hits 12% - large grain surpluses remain a problem. ? 9/1/29 - Fall Bust $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($89.7 billion) ____________________________________________> ($90.5 billion on 9/19) [Yield - 2.98%] ############################################## (92%) ? Brokers loans and other loans on securities rise sharply - call rates down to 8% to 10% - steel production slips - commodity prices join decline - England raises discount rate. ? |
$$$$ (3.8%) |
10/1/29 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($86.8 billion) _____________________________> ($60 billion on 10/29) [Yield - 3.23%] ########################################## (85%) ? Interest rates drop sharply in first week as brokers loans finally begin to fall - commodity prices fall sharply - steel production and prices slip - railroad car loadings join decline - stocks Crash ? 11/1/29 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($71.75 billion) _______________________> ($48 on 11/13) [Yield - 4.06%] ################################### (69%) ? Railroad car loadings drop 3% in one week - banks and brokers have trouble unloading holdings of distress stocks - brokers loans finally drop sharply, but other types of loans remain sharply higher. Bonds up - stocks crash again. ? 12/1/29 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($63.5 billion) [Yield - 4.4%] ############################## (59%) ? Retail sales remain good, wages remain high and interest rates are sharply lower, but auto, steel and other manufactures dive, unemployment rises and railroad car loadings remain low - stocks crash again. ? |
(-10%) $$$$$$$$$$ |
1/1/30 -
Spring Business Revival: $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($64.7 billion) [Yield - 4.39%] ##################################### (75%) ? Russia plans to sell wheat - subsidized prices induced farmers to plant huge spring crop - agricultural commodity prices dive. stocks up. ? 2/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($69 billion) [Yield - 4.29%] ######################################## (80%) _________________________________________>(82% in mid Feb.) ? Bumper European wheat crop reported, agricultural commodity prices dive - Farm Board pegs wheat prices sharply higher but thus destroys wheat exports - but retail sales, autos and steel push sharply up, railroad car loadings recover, interest rates are down - accelerated steel orders and maintenance projects from railroads and other major industrials - bankers and brokers finally succeed in unloading most distress stock from '29 Crash. ? 3/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($70.8 billion) [Yield - 4.17%] ####################################### (78%) ? Real estate prices fall, undermining 2nd mortgages, undermining rural banks. Failures up sharply for small banks and businesses. Commodity prices keep slipping. Textiles drop sharply, but autos, steel and most trade segments recover nicely. Stocks and bonds up. ? |
(-23%) $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ |
4/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($76.1 billion) _______________________________________> ($79 billion on 4/10) [Yield - 4.00%] ####################################### (78%) _______________________________________> (80% in mid Apr.) ? Steel prices slip - first quarter earnings are poor - commodity prices plummet. Railroad car loadings fall. Interest rates continue diving lower (no longer a factor). ? 5/1/30 - Disillusionment: $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($75.3 billion) [Yield - 4.23%] ################################### (70%) ? European copper cartel unable to sustain copper price peg - copper prices plummet. Farm Board unable to sustain wheat prices - broad retreat of commodity prices. Auto sales and production drop - steel prices and production slip - private construction falls - unemployment and business failures sharply higher. Retail volume remains good, with declines due mainly to lower prices. Chinese cease silver purchases - silver prices plummet - purchasing power of silver denominated currencies plummet - cotton and textiles plummet. Stocks down. ? 6/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($71.4 billion) [Yield - 4.16%] ############################## (60%) ? Auto sales and production and steel production drop sharply - Smoot-Hawley Tariff enacted - Europe retaliates - commodity prices collapse and retail prices drop - huge grain and cotton carryovers. Stocks whipsaw repeatedly, ending sharply down. ? |
(-23%) $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ |
7/1/30 -
Corn Drought and Fall Business Revival: $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($63.9 billion) [Yield - 4.80%] ########################### (54%) ? Commodity prices continue down, but spring revival supports second quarter auto and steel earnings - corn drought boosts corn above wheat prices - wheat used for cattle feed - all grains sharply higher. Stocks rebound. ? 8/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($67.25 billion) [Yield - 4.53%] ############################ (55%) ? Cotton and steel prices continue down. Drought breaks, tumbling corn and grain prices. ? 9/1/30 - Business and Agricultural Collapse: $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($67.75 billion) [Yield - 4.43%] ############################# (58%) ? Autos and railroad car loadings and other trade indices fall at time when trade usually picks up - commodity prices break to new Depression lows. Stock market decline resumes. ? |
(-25%) $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ |
10/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($60.14 billion) [Yield - 4.82%] ######################## (48%) ? Third quarter earnings bad - Russia sells additional 54 million bushels wheat plus cotton and other crops - significant numbers of dividends are omitted or reduced or maintained by dipping into previous earnings - auto sales and steel production plummet - retail sales fall - railroad bonds join decline. ? 11/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($55 billion) [Yield - 5.41%] #################### (39%) ? Small banks and businesses failing in record numbers - business and agriculture collapse. ? 12/1/30 $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$ ($53.3 billion) [Yield - 5.40%] ################ (32%) ____________> (24% last week in Dec.) ? First big N.Y.C. bank fails - foreign and domestic bond markets jolted by periodic defaults and rumors of defaults - domestic bonds plummet, stocks continue decline. |
(-30%) $$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$$
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2001 Dan Blatt