NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOK
Available at Amazon in
Hard cover, soft cover & ebook
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
A MONETARY HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES
(1867-1960)
by
Milton Friedman & Anna J. Schwartz
Part I: Greenbacks and Gold (1867-1921)
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 9, No. 5, 5/1/07
Introduction:
& |
The impacts of fluctuations
in the money stock run like a thread through the economic history of the United
States, Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz explain in "A
Monetary History of the United States (1867-1960)." This book takes in monetary developments during the Civil War that set the stage for
the post-Civil War period. |
Monetary factors played a major role in the economy's cyclical movements, "and conversely, non-monetary developments frequently had major influences on monetary developments; yet even together," there is much in business cycle history that they acknowledge is not covered in the book. |
The authors' major conclusion - from their analysis of 93 years of monetary history - is that:
The narrow focus of this book is emphasized by the authors. The money stock is influenced by other economic factors and influences those other factors in turn. Monetary factors played a major role in the economy's cyclical movements, "and conversely, non-monetary developments frequently had major influences on monetary developments; yet even together," there is much in business cycle history that they acknowledge is not covered in the book.
|
High-powered money and bank system money: |
The total money stock includes currency held by the public plus
money created through deposits in the commercial banking
system. |
The larger deposits get in relation to reserves retained by the banks and in relation to the currency in the hands of the public, the more bank system money is being created.
The amount added to the money stock by bank deposits depends both on the willingness of the public to use the banking system, and the amount of deposits bankers are willing and able to lend to the public over and above retained reserves. |
Money that can be used as liquid reserves for bank deposits is
considered "high-powered" money, since the fractional reserve banking
system serves to increase the total stock of money. In 1867, the public held
about $1.20 in deposits for each $1 in currency. This rose quickly to $2 by
1873,
reflecting the rapid rise of the commercial banking system. It stayed about at that
level until 1880, rose -with numerous spikes and troughs - to $12 in 1929, and
then fell sharply during the Great Depression - recovering just to $6 in
deposits for each $1 in currency in 1960. |
Price statistics leave much to be desired during this period, especially for
consumer or general price levels. The authors make use of indexes based on
calculated - or "implied" - prices, and so refer to
"implicit" prices rather than consumer or general prices. They rely
heavily on wholesale prices, since these are more available. |
A) Outline of Monetary History (1867-1921)
Greenbacks and the bimetal standard: The U.S. did not stiff its creditors to help pay for the vast expenses of the Civil War. |
The financial aftermath of the Civil War dominated
monetary and financial history until the beginning of 1879 when specie payments
were resumed - at the prewar parity. It was a struggle for the U.S. economy and
its people to maintain sufficient monetary restraint to drag prices back down to
a point where the "greenback" dollar would be "as good as gold." The U.S. did not stiff its creditors to
help pay for the vast expenses of the Civil War. |
Responding to the declining prices, politics were influenced by "greenbackism" and "Free Silver" movements that didn't end until the defeat of William Jennings Bryon in the 1896 presidential election. |
Even prior to 1879, gold was still
important for foreign transactions, since Great Britain and other important
European nations were on a gold standard. Gold could be purchased with dollars,
but its dollar price was free to fluctuate - upwards during the war and then
downwards back to parity by 1879. |
Birth of the Federal Reserve System:
& |
The nation's banking structure was subject to
periodic difficulties and panics during this period. 1873, 1884, 1890, 1893 and
1907 saw banking crises involving widespread fears, runs on banks, and
bankruptcies. In 1893 and 1907, most banks suspended payments on deposits,
causing money measures to decline while currency rose as the public withdrew
deposits during the panic. |
Even excluding WW-I, the Federal Reserve System failed to increase monetary stability. |
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 was the ultimate
response. It was designed to bring effective regulation at least for
Federal Reserve System member banks. The international gold standard weakened during WW-I, giving the new
Federal Reserve System (the "System") both greater freedom of action and increased
responsibility. The
Treasury had previously exercised a limited central banking role. The U.S. economy grew massively during this period, reducing the
relative importance of foreign trade and the impact of foreign influences on the
economy.
WW-I was financed in part by a rapid rise in the stock of money which was not stopped until early in 1920. This stoppage was "the first major deliberate and independent act of monetary policy taken by the System" and drew severe criticism as the economy tumbled into a depression. |
B) The Greenback Period (1867-1879)
Greenbacks:
& |
A "fiduciary standard" for paper
money unsupported by gold and freely floating against gold and other
currencies - dependent thus entirely on the credit of the issuer, the U.S.
government - existed from the Civil War until 1879. Gold money and
"greenback" paper money existed together and fluctuated against each
other. |
The total money stock consisted of gold, gold
certificates, U.S. notes - popularly called "greenbacks" - fractional silver currency,
other U.S. currency, national bank notes and subsidiary coinage and deposits in
commercial banks and mutual savings and postal savings banks. After 1914, it
also included Federal Reserve notes. |
With the end of the Civil War, the expansion of paper money ceased, prices declined, and the vigorous economic expansion that would vault the U.S. into the 20th century as an economic powerhouse commenced. This "coincidence cast serious doubts on the validity of the now widely held view that secular price deflation and rapid economic growth are incompatible."
By 1867, nearly 75% of the total money stock was of Civil
War origin - types of money that had not previously existed. These were
primarily national bank notes and U.S. "greenback" notes and
other U.S. currency. |
|
National bank notes grew rapidly to nearly $300
million by 1866. Growth continued slowly thereafter to $340 million by 1874, and
these notes remained an important part of the monetary system until 1935. They were backed
by requirements for 111% security in the form of government bonds bearing the
security privilege. They thus were actually indirect obligations of the federal
government. In the event of bank failure, the bonds would be forfeited to the
Treasury to be sold to redeem the bank money, and the Treasury had a first lien
on the bank's assets if more was needed. |
Greenbacks exceeded $350 million by 1867 -
fluctuated at levels below $400 million until 1878 reflecting political
controversy over their role in the 1870s price decline, and were then fixed
permanently at $347 million through 1960. |
|
The two moneys - greenbacks and gold or British sterling - fluctuated freely, and were thus able to coexist without one driving out the other. |
Gold coin and gold certificates were used
primarily for foreign exchange transactions. The gold "dollar" was
worth over $2 at the end of the Civil War - but declined rapidly to about $1.383
in June, 1867 and to about $1.10 in the 1870 to 1875 period. They thereafter
declined towards parity by 1879. |
The "depression" of 1873 to 1879: |
Money stock fluctuation in the 12 years before 1879
was comparatively modest. The money stock actually declined in 5 of the calendar years and
ended up only 17% higher for the whole period. |
Initiation of monetary movements typically precede the corresponding economic movements by some months. However, these monetary movements are often not turns but just a slowing or acceleration of the rates of growth. |
Monetary restraint was required
for the effort to make the greenback "as good as gold." Not until the sharp decline
during the initial years of the Great Depression do we find so many years of
money stock decline in any dozen year period. Indeed, including the 5 years 1929 to 1933,
there were only 13 single years of decline in the 81 years up to 1960. Because
of variations in statistical evaluation and availability, these calculations are
not always based on calendar years.
|
Fluctuations in wholesale prices tracked these monetary
movements. Wholesale prices declined significantly from 1867 to 1879, interrupted only by the cyclical
expansion 1870 to 1872 when money stock was also rising. The average decline
from 1865 to 1879 was an unprecedented 6½% per year as greenbacks rose back
to par with gold. In terms of gold, prices were practically stable. |
|
Velocity is a relatively stable magnitude, the authors assert.
The severity of the 1873 to 1879 depression may well be significantly overstated due to the weaknesses in the statistical data for that period. |
There are severe problems with the price statistics
available for this period, the authors warn. Farm produce and raw materials markets provided
readily available prices, but many other price levels were uncertain or are unavailable. With respect to farm produce and raw materials, technological
improvements - especially in transportation - were probably the cause of a substantial relative
decline in their prices during the period. The general price decline is estimated
on the bases of particular scholarly analyses producing an "implicit price
deflator" or "implicit prices." This implicit price decline was
running at around 3.5% per year.
Despite a mild recession trough in 1867 and a deep one in 1879, the
authors estimate output increased about 3.6% per year during this period for an
impressive increase of about 54%. A substantial increase in population of more
than 30% accounts for more than half of this increase in output. The latter part
of the 1870s experienced a worldwide depression, sending a wave of immigrants into the
U.S. despite U.S. economic difficulties. |
"In the greenback episode, a deflation of 50 percent took place over the course of the decade and a half after 1865. Not only did it not produce stagnation; on the contrary, it was accompanied and produced by a rapid rate of rise in real income." |
The available statistics make it appear that an extraordinary period of net national product increase and real per capita income increase corresponded with a period of apparent severe depression and price decline. The authors explore in some depth the relative unreliability of output and monetary statistics for this period and the various estimates of net national product.
Nevertheless, while many thrived, there were many losers. Businesses
closed, workers lost jobs and nominal wages declined. Although real wages
increased along with net national product, social problems were created and
political attention turned to the lack of growth in the greenback money supply. |
Greenback agitation grew after the banking panic of 1873. Greenback
inflation lost by the narrowest of political margins in 1878, after which it declined - to
be replaced by agitation for a bimetallic silver and gold monetary system. |
|
The determinants of the money stock under both fiduciary - or "fiat" - and specie
standards, are briefly set forth by the authors. They explain how a slow decline in greenbacks
and other currency was translated by the banking system into a modest rate
of increase in the money stock until that, too, began to decline during the 1875
to 1878 depression years. Changes in deposit-to-reserve ratios and deposit to
currency-in-the-hands-of-the-public ratios explain these movements. The greenback agitation failed to more than
marginally impact greenback circulation, leaving the banking determinants as the
most influential factors after 1867. |
Financing the Civil War: |
The authors illustrate the massive benefits
bestowed upon the nation by its carefully maintained good credit. They analyze the movements of gold prices and interest rates
during and in the 15 years after the Civil War. |
Investor confidence restrained the rise in the greenback price of gold and - just as important - kept long term interest rates at reasonable levels - thus massively facilitating the nation's ability to finance the war. |
As gold prices rose against the greenback during the war, the markets kept discounting a return to parity after the war rather than further devaluation of the greenback. This investor confidence restrained the rise in the greenback price of gold and - just as important - kept long term interest rates at reasonable levels - thus massively facilitating the nation's ability to finance the war.
Speculative money was parked in long term U.S. and private - mainly
railroad - bonds, whose yields were thus lowest precisely when gold prices were
highest and speculative interest in a greenback recovery would be greatest.
Short term call money and commercial paper were not convenient parking places
for such speculative money, and their yields rose as might be expected from the
concurrent inflation and heavy government borrowing. |
Payments in gold for gold bonds were maintained - apparently
much to the surprise of the market. While confidence that the greenback would
eventually return to parity was high, such was not the case for gold bonds. The
yield on the 6% 1881 bond exceeded 16% at one time during the war. The gold
bonds were discounted in line with the discount for greenbacks - so market
speculators made substantial profits as gold payments were maintained. Towards
the end of the war, yields declined sharply, with further declines after 1869
when the government committed itself to continue payments in gold.
The authors note that something similar occurred during the early stages of the German
inflation after WW-I - but the inflation continued and speculators lost heavily
for their misplaced faith in the Weimar government. |
Resumption of the gold standard:
\& |
With the end of the war, capital inflows continued - presumably now seeking permanent investment in the expanding U.S. economy. This supported the greenback at higher valuations than warranted by recovering trade levels. Gold declined from 20% above calculations of purchasing power parity to 10% below.
After 1873, gold fluctuated upwards, back to levels approximating
calculations of purchasing power parity. As U.S. bond yields declined, foreign
investors abandoned them in favor of the higher yielding railroad bonds - until
railroad bond defaults led to the banking failures and panic of 1873. |
This was a period of remarkably disciplined government budgetary and monetary policies which played a major role in supporting confidence in the monetary system. |
As resumption of specie payments at pre-Civil War parity neared, domestic
demand for gold increased both on the part of the public and the Treasury. The
greenback price of gold rose above purchasing power parity levels, exports were
drastically curtailed, and production of gold increased 50% between 1875 and
1878. |
C) The Gold Standard and "Free Silver" Movement (1879-1897)
The gold standard:
& |
Under the gold standard,
the
major channel of influence on the stock of money runs from "fixed rates of
exchange with other currencies through the balance of payments to the money
stock, thence to the level of internal prices that is consistent with those
exchange rates." |
"The forces making for economic growth over the course of several business cycles are largely independent of the secular trend in prices." |
Domestic policies can produce sizable short term deviations, however,
because the links are loose with plenty of play between them. Policies that
impact trade or capital flows or levels of money balances held by the public can influence the
system, but they ultimately have to be reversed or they will undermine the gold standard. |
The adjustment process of the gold standard:
& |
Resumption in 1879 was followed by an economic boom as monetary confidence was
reinforced by a massive two year surge in crude foodstuff exports responding to
major crop failures in other countries. Gold stocks more than doubled in these
two years from $210 million to $439 million. This caused an expansion of the money
stock that pushed up prices approximately 10% at a time when British
prices remained constant. British gold reserves declined 40%, inducing an
increase in its Bank rate in steps from 2½% to 6% - which reversed the gold
flow. |
The two year surge in U.S. crop exports and its ending resulted in an
apparent seesaw reaction in international gold flows. The gold flows kept
exchange rates steady and mitigated price fluctuations. However, the expansion
of the U.S. money stock did lead to price increases in the U.S. and put
downwards pressure on prices in the nations that paid in part in gold for
imported food. The relative price swings ultimately brought the systems back to
trade equilibrium and ended the need for large gold flows. "It would be
hard to find a much neater example in history of the classical gold-standard
mechanism in action," the authors note. |
End of the Free Silver movement: |
The Sherman Silver Purchase Act of 1890 doubled silver purchases,
which were paid for with Treasury notes redeemable in either gold or silver at
the discretion of the Treasury. |
The financial troubles of the 1890s were marked by the waxing
and waning of confidence in the maintenance of the gold standard - corresponding
swings
in capital flows - and several corresponding cyclical economic swings. World prices
in terms of gold fell sharply between 1891 and 1897 and the Free Silver movement reached
its political peak - further undermining confidence in the gold standard in the
U.S. Changes in tariffs and increased spending for
pensions, rivers and harbors threatened to reverse the budget surplus. |
|
A variety of currency substitutes were created - factory pay checks, miscellaneous notes and certificates issued by corporations and individuals. The situation was short lived - ending when deposit withdrawal restrictions were lifted that September. |
The panic of 1893 is explained by the authors as running from
the loss of confidence in the bimetallic gold/silver standard, causing an
external drain as gold and capital flowed out. This in turn caused a decline in
the money stock and declines in securities prices and general price levels.
Soon, banks, brokerages and mercantile establishments were failing. However,
bank failures were predominantly in the West and South due to an internal drain
caused by defaults on loans that undermined confidence in bank solvency. & Efforts to repeal the Sherman Silver Purchase Act began in the summer of 1893 and brought the external drain to an end. Repeal came on November 1, 1893. & As the public sought currency, public currency holdings rose 6% in the year ending June, 1893, while deposits fell 9½%. The total money stock fell about 6% - the first substantial decline since 1875-1878. A second round of deposit withdrawals hit the South and West in July, 1893, draining reserves from New York. When the Erie Railroad went into receivership, the stock market tanked and bank failures hit the East as well. & Banks then imposed restrictions on cash withdrawals, bringing the string of bank failures to a close. While reserves proved inadequate in certain banks, total reserves in the banking system were adequate. But currency was suddenly rendered scarce by the restrictions on deposit withdrawals. Currency thus began selling at a premium to bank deposits. A variety of currency substitutes were created - factory pay checks, miscellaneous notes and certificates issued by corporations and individuals. The situation was short lived - ending when deposit withdrawal restrictions were lifted that September. & |
World prices continued to fall and the British price
decline lasted into 1896 as gold continued to appreciate. Except for a modest 18 month rebound from the middle
of 1894, the deflation in the U.S. dragged on to 1897. Treasury gold reserves
fell below $45 million at the beginning of 1895. Speculative pressure on the
dollar persisted as did political agitation. Various measures kept the money
stock fairly constant and assured holders of dollar balances that the Treasury
was determined to maintain the gold standard. |
|
The perfervid politics of the greenback and Free Silver advocates
during the last quarter of the 19th century are summarized by the authors. These
forces succeeded in gaining passage of limited silver purchase and bimetal
standard legislation in 1878 and 1890, with repeal coming at the end of 1893.
The desired unlimited coinage of silver was never enacted. Limited silver
coinage and issuance of silver certificates undermined confidence in U.S. currency, but was
insufficient to stem the rapid decline in silver prices as copious supplies
rolled in from the West and other sources around the world.
|
Determinants of the money stock: |
The determinants of fluctuations in the money stock under
the resumed gold standard up to 1897 are analyzed by the authors. |
The initial 2½ year surge in the money stock to 1881
accounted for nearly half the total growth to 1897. Just over 80% was accounted
for by growth in "high-powered money" - primarily coinage and currency
backed by gold and silver and national bank notes. High-powered money growth
accounted for 55% of money stock growth from 1881 to 1892, but high-powered
money declined until
the middle of 1897, after which it sharply recovered. |
The deposit-to-currency-held-by-the-public ratio of the banking system vacillated as
might be expected with fluctuations in public confidence in the banking system. It grew strongly
with the successful resumption of the gold standard, thereafter flattening out
or contracting during business contractions and dropping sharply during the
panic of 1893. If monthly data were available, the authors note that the ratio
would undoubtedly show sharp declines corresponding to the banking crises of
1884 and 1890. Growth after the 1893 crisis made up for much of the decline in
high-powered money in that period and - along with growth in the
deposit-to-reserve
ratio after 1893 - kept the money stock essentially flat to 1897. |
|
High-powered money levels were determined mainly by gold flows
and silver purchases. However, there was considerable play in the system that
permitted responses to policy decisions. There was no legal category of
fiduciary currency during this period, so only the modest fiduciary element in
minor coins existed. |
|
The Treasury also played a monetary role. Treasury cash increased due
to revenue surplus and borrowing - both of
which subtracted from high-powered money in circulation. Revenue deficits and
debt repayments had the opposite effect.
Treasury cash declined from 1888 to 1893 due to debt redemptions in
excess of surplus revenues. This was a period of substantial growth of the money
stock coinciding with larger gold exports or smaller gold imports than would
otherwise have occurred. When silver monetization expanded in 1890, gold exports
soared as capital fled the country. The Treasury borrowed extensively from 1893 to 1896 to restore its gold
reserves, but this had the effect of contracting or preventing growth of the
money stock and probably contributed to the economic problems of that period. |
Silver: |
Silver legislation was intended to force inflation of the money
supply (and to keep silver mines profitable). |
The authors conclude that it was the bimetallist standard - rather than either a silver or gold standard - that was the primary source of instability, since the relative values of the two metals inevitably diverged on world commodity markets. |
The silver component of high-powered money grew steadily,
equaling about $500 million or about 1/3 of the total in circulation by 1893.
However, the authors point out, instead of causing an expansion of the money
stock as intended, it retarded growth prior to 1891 and played a major role in
the lack of growth thereafter. It undermined confidence in the maintenance of
the gold standard, adversely impacting capital and gold inflows and outflows.
Even after repeal of the silver legislation in 1893, Treasury borrowing to
acquire sufficient gold to restore confidence played a major role in monetary
stock stagnation until 1897. |
D) Inflation Under the Gold Standard (1897-1914)
Gold inflation: |
The surge in gold supplies resulted in
price inflation after 1897. |
Prices rose between about 40% or 50% from 1897 to 1914 - depending on the index used. This brought prices back to about the levels
reached in 1882 at the peak of the post-resumption expansion. This rate of price
inflation is unprecedented for the U.S. in peacetime (until the Keynesian
monetary policy inflation of the three decades after 1960). Inflation in the 1850s after the California gold
discoveries had been sharper but lasted for less than half the length of time. |
Expansion was fastest in the first five years - to June, 1902 -
as the system rebounded from the stagnant 1892-1897 period. It thus repeated the
pattern of the period after resumption two decades earlier. Wholesale prices rose 32% - about
2/3 of the total price rise for the entire period to 1914. Real net national
product rose more than 6% per year between 1896 and 1902 - 4½% per year per
capita. |
|
Treasury intervention became more regular in this period, with
actions to relieve monetary stringency at the end of 1899 and in 1901 - first to counter panic after a stock market collapse and later after
President McKinley was shot. These interventions did not prevent mild cyclical
contractions in 1899 to 1900 and for almost 2 years between 1902 and 1904, but
the contractions might have been much worse. The Treasury intervened twice
during the 1907 panic year. |
The panic of 1907:
& |
In England, gold was flowing out. The
discount rate was increased in steps from 3½% to 6% between September 13 and October
19, 1906. In Germany, the Reichsbank took similar steps. The seesaw impact then drew
gold back out of the U.S. |
By March, 1907, New York stock markets were in severe decline. Union
Pacific - a leading stock used widely as collateral in finance bill transactions
- dropped 30% in less than 2 weeks.
|
By September, 1907, however, the public and the banks were both
striving for liquidity - an impossible goal. Even though high-powered money rose
10% in 5 months due to gold imports and Treasury intervention equaling $64
million by the end of October, the money stock declined 5% - similar to the 1893
experience. The banks were unable to increase their currency holdings in the
panic month of October, but thereafter increased reserves by 8%, substantially
reducing both deposit ratios - enough to produce a 14% reduction in the money
supply but for the 10% rise in high-powered money. |
|
Unease affecting country banks continued, however, and was met with $256 million in clearing house certificates issued on the basis of high grade ordinary assets. In the 1893 panic, $69 million of these certificates had been issued. |
New York banks had to restrict the convertibility of deposits into
currency. Country banks soon followed their example. After announcement of the
restrictions, $31 million in currency drained out of the clearing house banks,
but the drain was only $8 million in the following 3 weeks. Seasonal inflows
then ended the currency shortage, and after October, currency began piling up in
the banking system. |
Many suspended banks were able to reopen later, and only unsound banks failed. Indeed, the total number of banks was probably higher at the end of 1907 than at the beginning. The measures taken to deal with the panic given the tools available seem to have been effective. |
The dispute over whether more aggressive intervention by the
big N.Y. clearing house banks could have prevented the panic is reviewed by the
authors. They note the vast increase in the deposit to currency ratio since 1879
- from $1 in currency for each $2 in deposits to $6 dollars in deposits in 1907.
The deposit- reserve ratio had doubled. |
The last years of the unfettered gold standard: |
The 1908 Aldrich-Vreeland Act was
a temporary effort to avoid such panics while
more thoroughgoing reforms were studied. It relied on bank issuance of emergency
currency based on usual bank assets with penalty provisions designed to force
retirement of the emergency currency after the emergency. |
"The prompt satisfaction of the public's demand for additional currency cut the [panic] process short at the outset." |
This mechanism was employed just once - at the start of WW-I - and successfully met the bank runs at that time. $400 million in clearing house loan certificates were issued, with $364 million the most in circulation at any one time - equal to almost a quarter of circulating currency and 1/8 of high-powered money. There was no panic and no need to restrict payments on deposits.
The period 1908 to 1914 was characterized by generally sluggish
growth with just two brief periods of buoyant expansion. Money stock, money
income and prices rebounded sharply from 1907 to 1910, with prices rising faster
in the U.S. than in Britain. The differential in price levels sent gold back to
Britain, slowing the growth of high-powered money. The sharp rebound in the bank
deposit ratios supported growth of the money stock. However, when that came to an
end, money stock growth slowed and the general business upsurge came to an end.
|
The rapidity with which the public regains confidence in the banking system when effective actions are taken to deal with panics is demonstrated by the speed with which the deposit-currency ratio recovers back to trend. |
Money stock and deposit ratios continued to increase, but at rates
considerably slower than those from 1897 to 1907. The deposit- reserves ratio,
however, didn't get back to its 1906 high during this period as banks reacted to
the 1907 panic by maintaining more prudent levels of reserves. |
Gold coins and gold certificates accounted for 87% of the
increase in high-powered money. Gold and national bank notes accounted for most
of the growth in currency held by the public. The Gold Standard Act of 1900
encouraged monetary growth by liberalizing the requirements for issuing national
bank notes and reducing to $25,000 the minimum capital for a national bank. The
Comptroller of the Currency was now required to accept eligible securities at
par rather than at 90% when issuing national bank notes to the banks. |
|
The authors compare two periods of relatively steady growth - each a decade long. One, from 1882 to 1892, occurred when prices were declining 2% per year, the other, from 1903 to 1913, occurred when prices were rising 2% per year. The periods show roughly similar growth in real output, and both begin just after a vigorous rebound from a monetary stringency episode.
The authors also speculate on long-swing theories of the business cycle. |
E) The Federal Reserve During World War I (1914-1921)
The Federal Reserve Act:
& |
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 came
into operation at the beginning of WW-I - a world it was not designed to deal
with. Suddenly, major nations abandoned or loosened their ties to the gold
standard as they sought flexibility to respond to the financial disruptions of
wartime conditions. |
The new Federal Reserve System (the "System") consisted of Federal Reserve Banks and a Federal Reserve Board (the "Board"), with policy making authority nebulously shared between the Board and the Federal Reserve Banks (the "Banks") - especially the influential N.Y. Federal Reserve Bank (the "N.Y. Fed."). The System was designed to assure sufficient "elasticity of currency" to avoid 1907 style panics. It was also (at last) intended to assure adequate supervision of its member banks, and to be able to rediscount eligible commercial paper to facilitate commerce. The System had an immediate impact on the money supply.
|
"The Federal Reserve System therefore began operations with no effective legislative criterion for determining the total stock of money. The discretionary judgment of a group of men was inevitably substituted for the quasi-automatic discipline of the gold standard." |
The Federal Reserve Act imposed a double requirement for
issuance of Federal Reserve notes. There was a gold requirement and an eligible
paper requirement. The latter involved the rediscount of
"eligible" high grade commercial paper, the discounting of foreign trade
acceptances, and open market purchases of government securities, bills of
exchange and bankers acceptances. In 1917, member bank 15-day notes secured by
paper eligible for discount or by government securities became eligible for the
issuance of Federal Reserve notes. By 1920, 69% of high-powered money was
Federal Reserve notes and member bank deposits in Federal Reserve Banks.
|
The Federal Reserve Act imposed a 40% gold reserve requirement for issuance of Federal Reserve notes, but only a 35% gold reserve requirement for Federal Reserve Bank deposits. |
Federal Reserve officials as yet did not understand the full
impact on the money supply of many of their activities. The authors mention the
increase in their holdings of bankers acceptances in the second half of 1928
while they were trying to restrict rediscounts - the former expanding the money
stock while the latter contracted it. The authors also point out that member bank deposits in Federal Reserve Banks act like high-powered money just like Federal Reserve
notes - yet had lower reserve requirements. |
WW-I inflation (1914-1920): |
Gold flooded into the U.S. as the Allies purchased their
wartime needs. Both during the period of U.S. neutrality and during its period
as a belligerent there were
extraordinary levels of monetary and price inflation. |
The money stock roughly doubled from September,
1915 to June, 1920. Prices almost doubled between the last quarter of 1915 and
May, 1920. Real net national product rose sharply to 1919 - with a pause from
1916 to 1917 - before declining in 1919 and 1920. This wartime inflation is
similar to experience in the Civil War and WW-II. |
During the almost three years as a neutral, the U.S. money
stock rose 46%. Growth in high-powered money accounted for 90% of money stock
growth, and gold accounted for 87% of the growth in high-powered money.
"This was straightforward gold inflation," the authors note.
At the time, the System still had not accumulated any substantial portfolio of
government securities. It thus could not have withdrawn money from the system by
open market sales of government securities even if it knew that that was
possible - which it apparently as yet did not know. |
|
A variety of wartime transactions require increased flows of currency - some having to do with tax avoidance. However, currency is actually the cheapest form of government debt, so the reduction in the bank deposit- currency ratio served to help finance the war. |
During the belligerency period - which for purposes of this
monetary history lasted from March, 1917, until 2 years after the November, 1918, Armistice - the Treasury advanced $9.5 billion to its allies.
Federal government deficits totaled $23 billion - nearly 75% of total
expenditures. This was financed by borrowing and issuance of new money - both
Federal Reserve notes and Federal Reserve deposits - which rose respectively to
38% and 21% of high-powered money by the time of the Armistice. Gold declined
during this time of belligerency to 14% of high-powered money. |
Gold ceased to be relied upon to fix exchange rates. (With
budgets wildly out of balance, flexibility to facilitate inevitable inflationary
adjustments was essential.) |
F) Boom and Bust Under the Federal Reserve System (1919-1921)
The depression of 1920-1921: |
The deposit to the public's currency holdings ratio reversed
its course soon after the Armistice, rising sharply as the public no longer had
need for so much currency. |
Commodity speculation and accumulation of inventories marked
the subsequent boom and would play a significant role in the
1920 to 1921 depression.
|
The Federal Reserve Board was at a loss as to what to do. The
Board hesitated as the money stock expanded vigorously and inflation roared on.
An increase in the discount rate would have posed difficulties for Treasury
funding operations. Rising interest costs always discomfort various powerful
financial interests that lobbied hard against it. Moral suasion -
"jawboning" in later terminology - was tried and - as always - failed
miserably. |
|
The Treasury decided it had
no further funding needs in December, 1919. It was flush with cash and it withdrew its opposition. Discount rates were
quickly raised to 4¼% and to 4¾%. Then, as reserves plunged, a second increase all the way up
to 6% came in the first two months of 1920 - "the sharpest single rise in
the entire history of the System, before or since." Fear of being forced
off the gold standard - of having to suspend gold payments - was a strong factor
in the close vote to raise the discount rate by a whopping 1¼%. Now with
access to the personal papers of some of the Board members, the authors recount
the feverish deliberations. |
Member banks had already borrowed
more than their reserve balances.
They at first reacted slowly to the contraction - but then sharply restricted
further lending. Money was shifted from demand deposits - a major
constituent of bank money - to time deposits. Money stock growth slowed - and then plunged 9% - one of the
largest declines since the Civil War. |
|
When the boom turned to bust, the Board received extensive
criticism first for its tardy action - permitting the boom to get out of hand -
and then for precipitating the sharp bust of 1920 to 1921. The authors agree with
this criticism. The economy may already have begun contracting even before the rate
hike took effect. Gold was already flowing into the U.S. - and the high discount
rate accelerated the flow, causing worldwide economic distress. The Fed Governor was not reappointed in 1922 - introducing
"an element of political instability" which inevitably impacted the
operations of the Board. |
The U.S. was a substantial cause of the post WW-I disturbances - no longer a victim of external events. The authors concluded that some difficulties might have been unavoidable due to the dislocations of the Great War, but instead of acting as a stabilizing force, the new Federal Reserve Board clearly made matters worse. |
The depression was worldwide. This was typical after a major
war. The economic adjustments to peacetime production and
absorption of wartime debts typically cause inflationary spurts followed by substantial
reactions. After WW-II, however, the U.S. was in a massively strong
financial position and suffered only a mild recession during the shift to
peacetime production. But it did not avoid the inflationary surge. |
"The contemporaneous gold reserve ratio was a simple easy guide; [the System goal of] economic stability, a complex, subtle will-o'-the-wisp." |
The System was a destabilizing factor from its beginning, the authors conclude. Federal Reserve money and looser reserve requirements materially increased money stock growth and price inflation throughout the war - monetary expansion and price inflation would have ended sooner after the war but for System monetary expansion - and the 1920 to 1921 depression would certainly have been more mild but for Fed policy errors. Lack of experience was evident throughout this period.
See, "Friedman & Schwartz, Monetary History of U.S.," Part II, "Roaring Twenties Boom - Great Depression Bust (1921-1933)," and Friedman & Schwartz, Monetary History of U.S.," Part III, "The Age of Chronic Inflation (1933-1960)." |
Please return to our Homepage
and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2007 Dan Blatt