NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOKS
available at Amazon in
Hard cover, soft cover, ebook
Trade War "Understanding the Great
Depression Explaining the Great Depression, its Trade War, and failures of "New" Keynesian interest rate suppression policy without ideological clap trap, theory confirmation bias or political spin. |
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
A MONETARY HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES
(1867-1960)
by
Milton Friedman & Anna J. Schwartz
Part II: Roaring Twenties Boom - Great
Depression Bust
(1921-1933)
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 9, No. 6, 6/1/07
Introduction:
& |
The
Federal Reserve System gained freedom of action after the unpleasantness of
the 1920 to 1921 depression, Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz explain in "A
Monetary History of the United States (1867-1960)." Its gold and other reserves were abundant, and the
Treasury had no major deficits to fund. |
The narrow focus of this book is emphasized by the authors. The money stock is influenced by other economic factors and influences those other factors in turn. Monetary factors played a major role in the economy's cyclical movements, "and conversely, non-monetary developments frequently had major influences on monetary developments; yet even together," there is much in business cycle history that they acknowledge is not covered in the book.
|
High-powered money and bank system money: |
The total money stock includes currency held by the public plus
money created through deposits in the commercial banking
system. |
Money that can be used as liquid reserves for bank deposits is
considered "high-powered" money, since the fractional reserve banking
system serves to increase the total stock of money. In 1867, the public held
about $1.20 in deposits for each $1 in currency. This rose quickly to $2 by
1873,
reflecting the rapid rise of the commercial banking system. It stayed about at that
level until 1880, rose - with numerous spikes and troughs - to $12 in 1929, and
then fell sharply during the Great Depression - recovering just to $6 for each $1 in currency in 1960. |
|
Price statistics leave much to be desired during this period, especially for consumer or general price levels. The authors make use of indexes based on calculated - or "implied" - prices, and so refer to "implicit" prices rather than consumer or general prices. They rely heavily on wholesale prices since these statistics are more available. |
A) Outline of Monetary History (1921-1933)
From 1920s prosperity to 1930s Depression:
The belief arose that the central banks could together assure both domestic and international stability. |
The 1920s were a period of general prosperity and monetary stability, with monetary growth proceeding at a regular rate. The reputation of the Federal Reserve System (the "System") soared, and it cooperated closely with the great central banks of Britain, France and Germany. The belief arose that the central banks could together assure both domestic and international stability.
|
The Great Depression began like previous depressions - although it was immediately sufficient not only to slow monetary expansion but to cause some decline in the money stock. By the end of 1930, however, this changed drastically, as bank runs, failures and crises reached unprecedented proportions.
By 1933, when a banking holiday brought the collapse to a conclusion, the money supply had declined by one-third, as had the number of banks through failure and merger. The Fed had the power to mitigate these contractions but failed to act - presumably because of a higher priority given to external than to internal stability. |
B) Roaring Twenties Boom (1921-1929)
Federal Reserve monetary policy: |
Promoting internal stability and balance in
international accounts and the prevention or moderation of financial
crises were the tasks of the Federal Reserve System (the "System"). |
The abnormally high rate of bank failures in the 1920s - concentrated in small, nonmember, agricultural sector banks - were attributable to lingering agricultural dislocations from WW-I and did not threaten confidence in the banking system as a whole. |
Extensive studies were undertaken on these subjects. The
prosperity and general stability of the 1920s seemed to indicate that these
tasks had been mastered. At various times, the System even extended credit to
foreign nations - Poland, Czechoslovakia, Great Britain, Belgium, Italy, France. |
The use of open market operations as well as
rediscounting as means of regulating the money markets was recognized before the
middle of the decade. A committee was organized to coordinate the buying and
selling of government securities for all the Federal Reserve Banks
(the "Banks").
The System had to learn how to use its tools. |
|
The gold standard had its problems, but it had provided easily understood answers and was generally effective in peacetime given reasonably responsible government financial policies. |
Unfortunately, the System remained uncertain as to when to use its tools. The "problem of devising criteria to replace the gold reserve ratio" remained unsolved. The gold standard had its problems, but it had provided easily understood answers and was generally effective in peacetime given reasonably responsible government financial policies. Quoting the System's Tenth Annual Report (for 1923) - which constituted an important analytical effort to guide policy - the authors note the vagueness of the guidance available.
This report emphasized the need to
"interpret" conditions and rely on "judgment" to do the
right thing at the right time, "with only the vaguest indications of what
is the right thing to do." |
The System's monetary policy tools were blunt instruments, and much confusion was created in trying to find ways to apply them that would discourage the speculative use of credit without constraining the commercial use of credit - an impossible task. |
There was concern about distinguishing
"productive" from "speculative" use of credit. The
commodities speculation that collapsed in the 1920-1921 depression remained very much in
mind. Concern about the speculative use of credit for securities transactions
would not arise until the stock market boom at the end of the decade.
Unfortunately, the System's monetary policy tools were blunt instruments, and
much confusion was created in trying to find ways to apply them that would
discourage the speculative use of credit without constraining the commercial use
of credit - an impossible task. |
Wholesale prices trended slightly lower throughout the period. Indeed, they didn't recover from their 1920s decline until after WW-II.
"Apparently the steadiness of the price movement is far more important than its direction." |
As usual, a buoyant expansion followed the severe contraction of 1920 to
1921. In the 22 months after the depression bottom,
industrial production rose 63%, the money stock expanded by 14%, and wholesale
prices rose by 9%. Net national product rose 23% in the corresponding two
calendar years. |
The state and federal banking authorities competed with each other to attract banks to their respective systems. They relaxed banking restrictions.
"The high prosperity of the twenties and the spreading belief in a new era understandably led to an increasingly optimistic evaluation of the prospects for repayment and hence to an increasing readiness to lend on a given project or collateral." |
The banking system underwent extensive changes in
the 1920s. The state and federal banking authorities competed with each other to
attract banks to their respective systems. They relaxed banking restrictions,
thus permitting substantial expansion of the types of activities engaged in by
banks.
|
Fluctuations in credit quality
are not a cause of the business cycle, the authors point out, but may contribute to its scope -
especially to the severity of contractions when they occur. It is as bad for the
economy to become too risk averse as to become recklessly venturesome. |
|
The Federal Reserve System contributed to confidence,
and thus contributed to the steady rise in the deposit to currency ratio. The
existence of the System as a lender of last resort induced member banks
to reduce their actual reserves closer to the minimum levels required. A market in
"federal funds" developed to facilitate interbank lending among member
banks - leading to further reduction of actual reserve levels. |
The gold exchange standard: |
The monetary gold stock rose significantly until
1927. However, this was offset by the rapid decline of Federal Reserve credit outstanding during
the 1920-1921 depression and 1923-1924 recession and by the minimal rate of recovery
of Federal Reserve credit outstanding thereafter. |
The Board decided to "sterilize" the gold inflow so it
wouldn't have an inflationary impact on the money supply and prices. The Board did this
by reducing or restraining the growth of its credit outstanding sufficiently to keep the money stock stable. |
The U.S. was inexperienced and unwilling to take the responsibility for its actions that was required of such leadership. Its short-sighted policies were narrowly self-interested and undermined financial stability worldwide.
If some nations sterilize gold flows, the full burden of the adjustment process - whether involving price inflation or price deflation - falls on the rest. |
WW-I left the U.S. as a leading player in this
system. Great Britain had played the leading role before WW-I, but the war left
her financially weakened. The U.S. was inexperienced and unwilling to take the
responsibility for its actions that was required of such leadership. Its
short-sighted policies were narrowly self-interested and undermined financial stability worldwide. It
became the bull in the financial china shop - blatantly heedless of the international impacts of its domestic policies. |
Britain's economy was no longer flexible enough to make such post-war adjustments.
"[If] gold flows had been permitted to affect the quantity of money they would thereby have set in motion forces tending to reduce their magnitude." |
But par proved to be too high. Britain's economy
was no longer flexible enough to make such adjustments. It suffered from persistent deflationary
pressures right into the Great Depression, contributing to the stagnant economic
conditions throughout Europe. U.S. gold sterilization policies (and high
tariffs) played a major role in the failure of Britain's efforts and the
destabilization of finances throughout Europe.
|
Criticism was justifiably directed at the U.S.
from around the world. (The U.S. directs similar criticism today at Japan and
China.) U.S. loans to foreign nations - Germany, Austria, Hungary, Rumania - and
the floating of foreign government bonds on the New York markets - prevented
earlier collapse - but were mere palliatives. As the financially weakest nations
experienced deflationary economic difficulties, these difficulties were in turn
transmitted to other nations (ultimately including the disastrous collapse of U.S.
export markets).
The authors point out that recovery in country after country followed abandonment of the gold exchange standard. This is used as proof that gold standards - and the U.S. as the dominant player - played a dominant role in the worldwide Great Depression. |
|
|
Federal Reserve System failure (I):
& |
Board monetary policy seemed effective during the
two business cycles in the mid-1920s. The Board raised discount rates one or two
half point steps to restrain the exuberance of growth - accompanied by open
market activities designed to drain money from circulation and reduce
credit - and reversed course as recessions developed - apparently
contributing to keeping them mild. But by 1926, the great stock market boom had
already begun. |
The record indicates that System operations actually
failed to mitigate the two mild recessions of the twenties - in 1923-1924, and
1925-1926. System credit outstanding declined in both. The System
significantly increased its holding of government securities. However, bills
discounted declined sharply and even open market purchases of bills declined.
Money stock growth slowed during these recession periods, but substantial increases in the
deposit to currency-in-the-hands-of-the-public ratio prevented any actual
decline. Indeed, the rising deposit
to currency ratio accounted for 54% of the 45% money stock increase between the
cyclical trough in July, 1921, and the August, 1929 peak. |
Despite no evidence of any price inflation, from
early 1928 the Board began raising its interest rates and selling its government
securities. It was reducing the money in circulation and credit availability. By that summer, the discount
rate was up to 5% and System holdings of government securities had been reduced from $600
million to $210 million. |
|
The Board persisted in emphasizing efforts to apply "direct pressure" on member banks to discourage the speculative use of System credit. |
The tug of war between the Board and the N.Y. Fed over this and lesser policy disputes had simmered throughout the twenties. George L. Harrison was governor of the N.Y. Fed., and Roy A. Young was governor of the Board until September, 1930, after which Eugene Meyer was governor of the Board. Details of these disputes over policy and control of bank activities pertinent to monetary policy, and control over the Open Market Investment Committee, are provided by the authors.
The question of whether System credit could be directed
away from speculative use raged throughout 1929. The N.Y. Fed voted to raise its discount rate to 6% eleven times, but each time the rate
hikes were disapproved by the Board. The Board instead persisted in emphasizing
efforts to apply "direct pressure" on member banks to discourage the
speculative use of System credit. |
Already, some were expressing fears that rate hikes would cause a depression worse that that of 1920-1921 - and that the response in Congress would lead to a loss of Board independence. |
However, the call money market in New York was
a major source of commercial financing as well as a major source of
speculator financing. Any effort to restrict lending through it could cause call
money interest rates to sky rocket and panic the
markets. (Call money short term interest rates had already been at and above 15% in March, April, June and July
1929, and had hit 20% in March.) |
In 1928, the Board decided that continuous indebtedness at the Reserve Banks was an "abuse of reserve bank facilities."
Indebtedness to the System came to be viewed as a sign of financial weakness, and made many banks reluctant to use the System rediscount facility. |
The System was a "lender of last resort,"
the Board emphasized. It was not a
source of continuous finance. In 1928, it decided that continuous indebtedness at the
Reserve Banks
was an "abuse of reserve
bank facilities." Its "Annual Report" for 1928 explained
that "the proper occasion for borrowing at the reserve bank is for the
purpose of meeting temporary and seasonal needs."
|
Confusion about its various monetary policy tools
continued into the Great Depression period. Board members drew invalid
distinctions between discounts of commercial paper and government securities.
This led to
inconsistent actions. Purchase and discounting of commercial paper was thought
clearly supportive of productive commerce, while purchase or discounting of
government securities increased money in circulation for any purpose -
speculative as well as productive. In reality, the authors note, the only valid
distinction is between System purchases and System discounts, since banks that are
already in debt to the System on the basis of discounted bills and notes are
somewhat more reluctant to expand their lending activities with the public.
|
|
The Board was paralyzed with respect to the blunt application of monetary constraints, and thus invoked "direct action" and "moral suasion" primarily "to demonstrate to itself and others that it was taking some action to meet clear and pressing problems." |
"Direct pressure," like "moral suasion," is doomed to disappoint, the authors conclude. In fact such efforts have shown only minimal impact whenever tried - as in 1919, 1929, and during WW-II until 1951.
The authors conclude that the Board was paralyzed with respect to the blunt application of
monetary constraints, and thus invoked "direct action" and "moral
suasion" primarily "to demonstrate to itself and others that it was
taking some action to meet clear and pressing problems." |
The Board finally agreed on a rate hike to 6% on
August 9, 1929 - hoping that it would not unduly affect seasonal credit in the
rest of the country. It considered preferential rates for agricultural paper or acceptances
drawn for the purpose of crop movements - negotiable bills of lading and
warehouse receipts. However, the rate for the purchase of
bills was already declining in steps to 5¼%. |
|
The Board had learned a lot about its monetary policy tools, but still faced fundamental conflicts of purpose.
|
Yet, the bust came anyway - with great virulence - and the economic system could not recover. Why? The authors provide only a monetary answer. |
The 1928 to 1929 boom had occurred without either monetary or price inflation. It was unaffected by the cyclical inflationary forces that usually accompany such cycles. And the Federal Reserve System played a major role in preventing the generation of those inflationary forces. Yet, the bust came anyway - with great virulence - and the economic system could not recover. Why? The authors provide only a monetary answer.
|
|
E) Great Depression Bust (1929-1933)
The Crash of '29:
& |
"The Great Contraction" is
what the authors call the first 3½ years of the Great Depression - from the
August, 1929 peak to the March, 1933 trough. See, seven Great Depression
Chronology articles beginning with The
Crash of '29, |
It was indeed a "great contraction" in every way - not just financial.
More than 20% of commercial banks - holding more than 10% of deposits
- suspended operations. With mergers and liquidations and consolidations, the
total number of banks fell by more than one third. A quarter of the workforce was unemployed at
the trough. The income gains of a quarter of a century had been erased.
|
The N.Y. Fed purchased $160 million in government securities - far in excess of anything contemplated by the System's Open Market Investment Committee - to expand liquidity in the N.Y. market. There was no bank panic. The panic was confined to the stock market. While already severe, there was nothing apparently unusual during the first year of the Great Depression.
The bank arrangements were unwound in the following months - at a profit.
This was the highest deposit to currency ratio on record other than a short spike during the Crash. Clearly, the public still had great confidence in its banking system. |
A flight of capital hit the markets for brokers loans and other credit during the 1929 stock market crash. Out-of-town banks and foreign banks, often acting as agents for investors, had been funneling vast sums into the brokers loan market. They now withdrew $4.5 billion - (just under 50% of the total) - from the brokers loan market.
The N.Y. City banks stepped into the breach, supported by open market
purchases by the N.Y. Fed to increase member bank reserves. The
N.Y. Fed purchased $160 million in government securities -
far in excess of anything contemplated by the System's Open Market Investment
Committee - to expand liquidity in the N.Y. market. There was no bank panic. The panic was confined to the stock market. While already severe, there
was nothing apparently unusual during the first year of the Great Depression.
Monetary
gold stocks declined as
foreign money continued to be withdrawn from the N.Y. money market. The stock of
money thus declined in November, but recovered in December due mainly to shifts
in demand deposits. The money stock trended a bit lower until the October, 1930,
banking crisis. |
The banks showed no inclination to increase their reserves during this period. |
The discount rates of the N.Y. Fed were
rapidly dropped in steps to 2½% by June, 1930 - but discounts declined
sharply anyway. Demand for bank loans had dropped sharply as capital fled to
safe assets. Money market interest rates also dropped sharply - even more
sharply - reducing the attractiveness of discounting at the Fed.
|
There is no sign of any flight to liquidity. Currency in circulation declined much more than bank deposits, and there was no special effort to expand bank reserves.
|
Federal Reserve System failure (II):
& |
The first banking crisis began in October, 1930, involving
primarily small banks in agricultural areas. By the end of November, banks
holding about $550 million in deposits were involved. (There had been a great
collapse of agricultural commodity prices in the first half of 1930, which
resumed in the second half and was joined at various points by the price
collapse of many industrial commodities.) |
These bank runs resulted
in the first substantial increase in currency in circulation during the Great
Depression. It naturally initiated efforts by banks to strengthen their reserves. There was
also a shift of deposits into the postal savings banks. Deposits there would
increase from $100 million in 1929 to $1.1 billion in March, 1933. |
|
The existence of the Federal Reserve System - with its discounting facility - relieved the stronger member banks of any perceived need to engage in the concerted action needed to stabilize the situation. |
Then, in December, the Bank of United States, with $200 million
in deposits, failed in New York - the largest commercial bank failure up to that
time. (Its large portfolio of building and real estate mortgages had been hit
hard.) Details of the efforts to save it are provided by the authors.
|
Confidence began to erode after the October, 1930 banking
crisis. This was reflected in rapid declines in the two bank deposit ratios.
These declines resulted in a 3% decline in the money stock in three months from the end
of October, even though high-powered money rose 5%. Federal Reserve System credit
outstanding rose $117 million - helping to offset some of the effects of the
banking crisis. However, System credit outstanding was still just 84% of its
summer 1929 level. The discount rate was lowered to 2%. |
|
Corporate bond prices were by now being affected.
Prices fell as investors sought liquidity or the safety of government bonds. The
capital adequacy of the banks was undermined by the falling prices of their bond
holdings.
The authors do note the worsening financial turmoil in Europe during
this period - as
major banks closed in Austria and Germany and elsewhere. The Hoover Moratorium
on international loan payments was agreed to in July, 1931, and loans were arranged in the U.S. and France for Great
Britain - providing some temporary relief for the hard pressed pound. (But
temporary relief was not sufficient because the Great Depression was not
temporary.) |
Devaluation of the pound: |
The second banking crisis ran from March, 1931, into the
British devaluation crisis in September. |
The deposit ratios nose-dived as deposits were withdrawn and banks sought to strengthen their reserves. |
Confidence was fragile to begin with, as might be expected by this time, and was shattered by the renewed troubles
in the banking system. The deposit ratios nose-dived as deposits were withdrawn
and banks sought to strengthen their reserves - driving down the money stock 5½% in six months even though high-powered money rose 4% during the four months
from March. |
The decline in the money stock accelerated, and the Board did almost nothing to stem the tide. |
Now, capital, and gold, were flooding into the U.S. - but U.S.
banks were left holding substantial amounts of the frozen short-term dollar obligations of
foreign banks. Worldwide, everybody was seeking liquidity and banks were trying
to strengthen their reserves. As banks liquidated their bond portfolios or fled
to the safety and liquidity of government bonds, the price decline in corporate bonds accelerated. |
The banking system was now being drained externally as well as internally. |
When Britain was forced off the gold standard in September,
1931, and the pound was devalued, the worldwide financial crisis reached catastrophic proportions. Two dozen other countries quickly followed. Suddenly, gold was king.
Not even the dollar was trusted. More than $700 million in gold flowed out of
the U.S. gold stock in little more than 6 weeks. |
This would have been another opportunity for a
pre-Federal Reserve Bank system to stabilize the system by temporarily
restricting payments on deposits, the authors assert. This "likely would have prevented at
least the subsequent bank failures." They note the business revival in late
August and early September (but fail to mention that this was the usual
seasonal business increase and how much more modest it was than in 1930). |
Federal Reserve System failure (III): |
The Federal Reserve System reacted decisively
to the external gold
drain. |
Gold became the primary concern of the N.Y. Fed. It raised its discount rate twice in
October - up two whole points - the fastest increase in the history of the
System. The gold outflow was stopped in its tracks - and so was the U.S.
economy. (The U.S. economy was already in sharp decline, as indicated by
declining railroad car loadings and steel production for several weeks prior to
the discount rate increases.) In 1932, the discount rate was reduced - but only back to 2½%. |
"It was the necessity of reducing deposits by $14 in order to make $1 available to the public to hold as currency that made the loss of confidence in banks so cumulative and so disastrous." |
Bank runs and failures accelerated. In the 6 months through January,
1932, 1,860 banks with $1,449 million in deposits suspended operations. Five times that amount drained away
from the deposits of the rest as
faith in banks crumbled. The money stock fell by 12% in those 6 months - the
fastest decline ever. Banks were driven to access the System's discount facility
in the two months after the devaluation of the British pound despite the higher
rates. However, this was all unwound by January, 1932.
|
At no time during the first three years of the Great Depression were gold reserves inadequate to support aggressive monetary policy - including substantial open market purchases. |
System gold reserves at the start of the British devaluation crisis were
over 80% of System note and deposit liabilities in July, 1931, 74.7% in September,
and didn't fall below 56.6% in October during the rapid outflow of gold. It was
in excess of required reserves by well over $1 billion at its lowest. At no time during the first three years of the Great Depression were
gold reserves inadequate to support aggressive monetary policy - including
substantial open market purchases.
Despite the 3½% discount rate, banks were now borrowing heavily
from the System - the burden falling hardest on banks outside the financial
centers. They were now liquidating their most basic assets - government bonds
and negotiable commercial paper. Government bond prices declined precipitously -
by 10% - for the first time during the Depression, and commercial paper yields
rose with the precipitous rise in the discount rate, lowering their prices. High
grade corporate bonds declined 20%, and lower grade bonds declined even more.
Railroad bonds fell off the eligible list for securities satisfying minimum bank
reserve requirements. |
Various financial measures - a private National Credit
Corporation formed in October, 1931 - and the Reconstruction Finance Corporation
("RFC") established in January, 1932 - were tried with no more than
limited temporary impact. The Glass-Steagall Act of 1932 passed in February. It broadened the collateral eligible at the Federal Reserve System, and widened
the circumstances under which banks could borrow from the System. In July, 1932,
the Federal Home Loan Bank Act authorized the organization of federal home loan
banks to make advances to savings institutions on the security of first mortgages. Various reform and relief measures outside the financial
sector were also proposed - and some were enacted - but to little avail. & |
Federal Reserve System failure (IV):
& |
In April, 1932, pressure from Congress
finally forced action.
1932, after all, was an election year, and all manner of price support schemes
were being proposed in Congress. By this time, system gold reserves had climbed
to 70%, and it was finally recognized as inexcusable to not use these great
financial resources to support the crumbling financial system. |
By this time, system gold reserves had climbed to 70%, and it was finally recognized as inexcusable to not use these great financial resources to support the crumbling financial system. |
The Conference of Reserve Bank governors added $500 million to the executive committee purchase authorization, and directed immediate implementation. $100 million of government securities per week were purchased in the next five weeks. Another $500 million was authorized in May. By the end of June, $1 billion in government securities had been purchased - but $500 million in gold had fled and there had been a $400 million reduction in bills bought and discounted - for a mere $100 million net increase in System credit outstanding. There had been no apparent impact on the economy.
This could have gone on considerably further, but not indefinitely.
The gold reserve ratio in N.Y. had fallen to 50%. It was 58% for the System as a
whole. Several of the other Federal Reserve Banks - especially in Boston and
Chicago - opposed the program and wouldn't participate. |
There are some who believe that July, 1932, marked the trough of the
Great Depression. There were sharp declines in all interest rates. Wholesale
prices, agricultural prices and industrial production increased - and the lowest point in the
spectacular decline of stock market values was finally reached. The stock market bottom came in July, with N.Y. Stock Exchange
capitalization down to about $15 billion.
|
|
|
|
Member bank reserves were now in excess of legal requirements, but not in excess of prudence given the course of events. Thus, the authors again argue, System open market purchases would not have merely supplemented bank reserves, but would have facilitated bank lending activities and reduced the decline in deposits.
There was no real recovery - and the financial strain
again took its toll among the banks. The collapse was becoming general, as
depositors fled with their cash - when they could get it. Perhaps $1
billion in scrip was in circulation in various localities. |
Collapse of the Federal Reserve System: |
The Conference was anxious to begin unloading
its government securities holdings - and actually began sales in January 1933 - when events
interrupted its plans. Soon, modest purchases resumed in vain efforts to stem
the torrent. There was no Conference meeting in February, as the System broke
down under the pressure of events. |
"In the final two months prior to the banking holiday, there was nothing that could be called a System policy. The System was demoralized." |
The final banking crisis from January to March, 1933, repeated
past patterns - only worse. For this short period, money stock declined 12%.
Discounts rose, leading to some increase in high-powered money, but the deposit
ratios crashed. The bank holiday in March rendered that month's statistics
non-comparable.
|
There was a flight from the dollar. Everybody was seeking gold and foreign currencies. |
Faith in the
dollar was evaporating with the approach of the new administration of Franklin Delano
Roosevelt ("FDR") and the expectations of dollar devaluation. The internal drain was now in part gold and gold coin. The drain on N.Y. banks was now external as well as
internal. There was a flight from the dollar. Everybody was seeking gold and foreign currencies. |
During this five month long interregnum period, both Pres. Hoover and Pres. elect Roosevelt refused to act - either alone or together. |
The Federal Reserve System raised its discount rate to counter
the external drain, but conducted practically no open market purchases. It did
raise its buying rate on acceptances, but attracted only small amounts of bills.
But banks were driven to discount bills even at the higher discount rates and to
dump securities on the market, sharply pushing up interest rates.
|
The banking holiday: |
On March 6, Franklin Delano Roosevelt,
the new President,
declared a nationwide banking holiday and suspended gold redemptions and shipments abroad. |
There had been similar restrictions, the authors point out - in 1814, 1818, 1837, 1839, 1857, 1873, 1893 and 1907 - but few banks had actually totally shut down - even for one day. Commerce had not been seriously disrupted. There had been some pressure to increase reserves, but that impacted the money stock generally for no more than a year.
|
The 1933 suspension for the first time involved suspension of
all payments - not just payments of deposits into currency. Over 5,000 banks
failed to resume business at the end of the bank holiday - over 2,000 were
permanently closed. This suspension clearly had come too late to be therapeutic. |
|
The refusal of FDR to deny rumors of intent to devalue led to months of gold outflows that undermined the whole system. |
The Federal Reserve System refused to act, and the
RFC loans were almost useless - branding the borrowing banks as weak and taking
their best assets as collateral. |
F) The Power and Limitations of Monetary Policy
Paralysis of the Federal Reserve System:
& |
From the October, 1930 banking crisis, the bank deposit ratios
declined so precipitously that the money stock went into substantial decline
even though high-powered money persistently rose. This reflected the extent to
which confidence in the entire banking system was eroding over time. The money
stock declined a whopping 35% from August, 1929 to March, 1933. (But the
implicit price decline of about 25% increased the purchasing power of the money
that remained in circulation, reducing the impact of the money stock decline.) |
More than 9,000 bank suspensions occurred in the four years
1930 through 1933 - 3,500 after the bank holiday. They resulted during the four
years in losses to depositors estimated at $1.3 billion, $0.9 billion to bank
stockholders and something in the neighborhood of $300 million to other
creditors.
|
But it was the inaction of the Federal Reserve System that permitted the increasingly destructive waves of bank failures, the authors assert.
|
|
The Federal Reserve System at all levels was aware of the
damage to confidence caused by the failure of the Bank of the United States in
December, 1930. Policy discussions on the subject thereafter occupied the
attention of the Board, the Federal Reserve Banks, the boards of member banks and the Open Market Policy Committee. However, the "general tenor of
the System comments, both inside and out, was defensive, stressing that bank
failures were a problem of bank management which was not the System's
responsibility." |
The N.Y. Fed and George L. Harrison, its governor, generally favored aggressive monetary intervention - preferably through open market purchases of government securities - to extend System credit into the banking system, reduce pressures on the banking system and encourage bank lending. (This assertion is disputed by Meltzer, "History of Federal Reserve," vol. 1, Part II, at segments on "Failure of the administered alternative" and "Panic," where Harrison's extraordinarily cautious attitude is convincingly demonstrated.) However, only during the 1929 stock market crash did it feel independent enough to act without Board approval. Despite the effectiveness of those actions, it was criticized by most of the System officials.
The result of this criticism and pressure from the Board was that
Harrison felt the N.Y. Fed could no longer act independently to meet crisis
conditions that subsequently arose. Its discount rate and acceptance rate
decisions were frequently rejected by the Board and thus delayed. It managed to
use existing authority to purchase $180 million of government bonds to extend
System credit into the N.Y. banking system when the Bank of the United States
failed in December, 1930 - clearly to good effect - but hard money sentiment on the Board forced it to
unwind this position by February, 1931. |
|
The authors provide extensive coverage of the policy disputes and
bureaucratic maneuvers between the Board, the N.Y. Fed, the Open Market
Investment Committee of five of the twelve Bank governors, and the Open Market
Policy Conference of all 12 governors that succeeded the Committee in 1931. The
new Conference was more bureaucratic and was given less authority than the
old Committee. The Conference's decisions were executed by a five member executive
committee. |
There simply was widespread doubt "as to the power of
cheap and abundant credit, alone, to bring about improvement in business and in
commodity prices." After all, short term interest rates were quickly
hitting rock bottom. Money was already "cheap" (but credit was not
"easy" as the Depression caused a widespread and continuing adverse shift in
credit worthiness). |
|
However, with all speculation driven out of the
markets, and the banking system still making full use of its assets, the authors respond,
"any
expansion of credit would likely be - - - restricted to productive uses." |
Opportunities for monetary intervention: |
The authors argue that the $1 billion in open market purchases
of government securities in 1932 that was insufficient to materially affect
matters at that late stage might have been more than adequate at earlier stages. |
If implemented at the beginning of 1930, it would have reversed the decline in the money stock, supported bank reserves, and led to expanded lending activities, since banks were still fully using their resources. It also would have reversed the gold inflow, relieving financial pressure abroad. The first bank panic at the end of the year would have been avoided or greatly reduced.
|
If implemented at the beginning of 1931, it would have had similar results. The second banking crisis would have been avoided or greatly reduced.
|
|
If implemented in September, 1931, in response to the British
abandonment of the gold standard and devaluation of the pound, it would have
fulfilled the second requirement of the classic response to such crises - not
only to counter the outflow of gold with high discount rates, but to avoid
internal distress by "a policy of free lending."
|
|
|
See, Friedman & Schwartz, "Monetary History of U.S." Part I, "Greenbacks & Gold (1867-1921," and Friedman & Schwartz, "Monetary History of U.S.," Part III, "The Age of Chronic Inflation (1933-1960)." |
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2007 Dan Blatt