NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOKS
available at Amazon in
Hard cover, soft cover, ebook
Trade War "Understanding the Great
Depression Explaining the Great Depression, its Trade War, and failures of "New" Keynesian interest rate suppression policy without ideological clap trap, theory confirmation bias or political spin. |
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
A MONETARY HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES
(1867-1960)
by
Milton Friedman & Anna J. Schwartz
Part III: The Age of Chronic Inflation (1933 to 1960)
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 9, No. 7, 7/1/07
Introduction:
& |
The monetary role of gold in the United
States and the world was greatly reduced by New Deal policies, Milton Friedman and
Anna J. Schwartz explain in "A
Monetary History of the United States (1867-1960)." As a result, as might
be expected, the United States and nations that pegged their domestic
currencies to the dollar persistently suffered fluctuating levels of
inflation from 1933 through 1960 (and entered an age of chronic
inflation). |
The narrow focus of this book is emphasized by the authors. The money stock is influenced by other economic factors and influences those other factors in turn. Monetary factors played a major role in the economy's cyclical movements, "and conversely, non-monetary developments frequently had major influences on monetary developments; yet even together," there is much in business cycle history that they acknowledge is not covered in the book.
|
High-powered money and bank system money: |
The total money stock includes currency held by the public plus money created through deposits in the commercial banking
system. |
Under the New Deal, the retirement of the national bank notes was provided
for, but as of the end of 1960, there was still an estimated $55 million
in circulation. Much of this had undoubtedly been lost or destroyed after almost
a century of circulation, and much is secluded in numismatic collections. With
the nationalization of gold, the currency included Federal Reserve notes, silver
certificates and subsidiary silver and minor coins. |
A) Outline of Monetary History (1933-1960)
The search for stability:
Federal deposit insurance ended the occurrence of periodic bank panics that had plagued the economy.
& |
The New Deal reaction to the Great Depression included:
|
The U.S. government was no longer so concerned about its credit or its creditors as after previous major conflicts, so monetary inflation became viewed as a convenient means of paying down government debts and price inflation became chronic.
"No country succeeded in curbing inflation without adopting measures that made it possible to restrain the growth of the stock of money." |
With the reopening of the banks in 1933 and the
restoration of confidence in the banking system, deposits and money supply rose sharply. Soon,
political turmoil and then the
threat of war in Europe sent gold fleeing from Europe to the U.S. The Board responded by doubling reserve requirements over a six month period beginning in
1936. This coincided with a sharp relapse in the Depression in 1937 and 1938,
which was probably worsened by the Board action and may actually have been
triggered in substantial part by that action. |
Banking and currency reform: |
Emergency
banking and currency measures were enacted during the banking holiday. |
The 1933 Emergency Banking Act extended the
President's wartime powers over banking and currency to peacetime national
emergencies. He was empowered to regulate or prohibit payment of deposits. |
The end of the banking holiday came on March 13, 14
and 15, 1933. Less than 12,000 member and nonmember banks began reopening under
System and state licensing procedures. Over 2,000 of the 17,800 banks in
existence before the banking holiday never reopened. |
|
There was rapid economic recovery after the banking holiday ended - much of which was due simply to the immediate reopening of the banking system and the gradual restoration of confidence in it.
|
|
The U.S. remained the bull in the international monetary china shop - heedless of the impact of its domestic policies on other nations and on international commerce. |
U.S. gold accumulation policies and sterilization of gold
continued to be a problem for gold standard nations until the total collapse of
the international gold standard system in 1936. In addition, U.S. silver accumulation policies
drained silver from silver standard nations and quickly caused collapse of those
monetary systems, also. The U.S. remained the bull in the international monetary
china shop - a young irresponsible giant - heedless of the impact of its domestic policies on other nations
and on international commerce. & |
Deposit insurance with very extensive coverage greatly reinforced depositor confidence in the banking system. Bank panics and widespread runs were eliminated. |
Radical improvements in the nation's banking systems
were made by the Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935. The authors emphasize deposit
insurance as the most important of the reforms. |
The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (the
"FDIC") was created to administer the program. It supplemented and
duplicated the powers of existing agencies.
|
Earnings were so low on bank assets in the 1930s and 1940s that, instead of offering interest to attract deposits, banks instead began imposing service charges for the service of holding them. |
There were a variety of other banking changes.
Eligibility for System membership was expanded to include Morris Plan and mutual
savings banks. Branch banking was slightly liberalized. Double liability for
stockholders in
member banks was eliminated. Their shares were no longer subject to additional
assessment to cover bank obligations. Investment banking was separated from
commercial banking.
|
The Board was authorized - within statutory limits - to set reserve requirements, an important increase in its monetary policy powers. The Banks were permanently authorized to make advances to member banks on any satisfactory security at any time. The Board was authorized to set margin requirements for bank and brokers loans to securities investors. |
The authority of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(the "Board") was enhanced and governors were given higher salaries and status and
longer terms. The Federal Open Market Committee (the "FOMC") was
changed under this new name to consist of seven members of the Board and five
representatives of the Federal Reserve Banks (the "Banks"). Board
members were now all entitled "governor" and executive heads of the
Banks were entitled "presidents." |
These were additional tools of monetary policy. They
were tools of
control over credit and over its price and use. They were tools of banking supervision. & |
New Deal economic and monetary policy: |
There were also command economy experiments
to
establish
cartel prices fixed above market levels. The National Recovery Act
(the "NRA") promulgated "codes," and the Agricultural
Adjustment Administration established production controls. |
Surviving banks stressed liquidity in their excess reserve positions and by favoring shorter term securities and marketable securities over loans. This continued throughout the 1930s.
Bank standards for loans became extraordinarily tight. Working capital loans of sound businesses were liquidated. |
Surviving banks stressed liquidity in their excess reserve positions and by favoring shorter term securities and marketable securities over loans. This continued throughout the 1930s.
As a result, banks soon held 50% of the U.S. bills -
which mature in less than one year when issued - and notes - which mature
between one and five years when issued. U.S. bonds mature in more than 5 years
when issued. The demand for these bills and notes was such that yields dove to
ridiculous fractions of one percent (0.014% in 1940). This increased the
attractiveness of holding cash, since little interest income was being given up.
|
The gold exchange standard: |
The FDR administration nationalized gold in 1933. |
Gold payment clauses in public and private contracts were abrogated - an action upheld by a 5-to-4 decision of the Supreme Court. |
It ordered holders to surrender gold and gold certificates above $100 in return for other currency or deposits
to be provided at the legal price of $20.67 per fine ounce. Exceptions were made for
industrial and artistic use in reasonable amounts, and for rare coin
collections. The "export" of gold was forbidden unless authorized by
license from the Secretary of the Treasury. |
The gold purchase program forced deflationary adjustments on remaining gold standard countries. U.S. demand for gold pushed up its relative value - reducing prices in terms of gold for everything else. |
As the dollar devalued, the dollar price of commodities
rose on world markets - as the administration desired. Financial
adjustments to accommodate these extraordinary activities went smoothly under
floating exchange rates. The primary impact was the adverse change in the terms of trade that is
the usual result of
currency devaluations. |
The government reaped the benefit of the dollar appreciation of gold - completing an expropriation of 60% of the value of the gold seized and imposing an implicit tax on all money balances. Henceforth, the transfer of gold bullion was limited to settlement of international payments balances. |
The U.S. quickly returned to fixed exchange rates
- at $35
per ounce - a devaluation of almost 60% - on
January 31, 1934, under the Gold Reserve Act of 1934. The government took title to all gold coin and
bullion, gold coinage ceased and gold coins were melted into bullion. The
Federal Reserve System replaced the RFC as a purchaser of gold. The government
assumed authority over all international transactions and imposed complete
reporting requirements. It reaped the benefit of the dollar appreciation of gold
- completing an expropriation of 60% of the value of the gold seized - and
imposing an implicit tax on all
money balances. Henceforth, the transfer of gold bullion was limited to settlement of international
payments balances. |
When reductions brought reserves down near the 40% requirement in 1945, the reserve requirement was just reduced to 25%. Price inflation would henceforth be no more than kept in check. Reversing inflation would no longer be a concern. Existing creditors were stiffed - and future creditors would have to factor chronic inflation into their lending calculations. |
The gold reserve requirement is no longer viewed
as a limiting factor in the issuance of currency. When reductions brought
reserves down near the
40% requirement in 1945, the reserve requirement was just reduced to 25%. Price inflation would
henceforth be no
more than kept in check. Reversing inflation would no longer be a concern. Existing
creditors were stiffed - and future creditors would have to factor chronic
inflation into their lending calculations.
|
Gold production soared in the U.S. and around the
world - more than doubling in the U.S. by 1940 and increasing more than 60%
worldwide. The weight of gold held by the Treasury more than tripled - to 630
million ounces - 1¾ times aggregate world output during that period. U.S.
gold reserves hit
an all time high in 1949, but were on their way down already - at 510 million
ounces - in 1960 (on the way to the devaluation crises of the 1970s). |
C) History of Monetary Silver (1792-1960)
Monetary silver: |
The periodic rises and falls of monetary silver took another
turn at this time. |
The history of the nation's bimetallic money system
runs back to 1792, when the price for monetary silver was set at $1.2929 per ounce. From 1834,
monetary gold was overvalued, pushing the market price of silver higher than
$1.29+, so none was coined. With the exception of the greenback period during and
after the Civil War, the U.S. was on a gold standard from 1834 to 1873. |
The Thomas Amendment to the 1933 Agricultural
Adjustment Act provided sweeping authorization for the purchase of silver.
The Amendment was intended to expand the money supply and support the price of
silver for the benefit of the silver mining industry. It authorized the purchase
of silver at over 64¢ an ounce. The market price at the end of 1933 was about
44¢. The U.S. Treasury quickly became the purchaser of all domestic silver
offered. |
|
The domestic results of this silver purchase program
were that 2,210 million ounces were purchased abroad on the world market.
Roughly $2 billion was spent from December 31, 1933. The purchase program by itself
failed to either raise silver prices to $1.29+ or bring silver stocks to the one-third relationship with gold. The closest it came until the gold drain of the
post WW-II inflation was 1 to 5.
Over $2 billion in additional silver certificates were in
fact issued - another purpose of the program. However, the authors speculate
that this probably did not increase the stock of money that much. The silver
certificates may simply have substituted for some Federal Reserve notes. The
other purpose - to support the silver industry - cost anywhere between $5 and
$25 for each $1 of benefit delivered to the silver miners - a rate of
inefficiency remarkable even for government programs. |
|
"The silver program is a dramatic illustration of how a course of action, undertaken by one country for domestic reasons and relatively unimportant to that country, can yet have far-reaching consequences for other countries if it affects a monetary medium of those countries." |
The program had international consequences, however. Once again, the U.S. was the young, heedless giant - the bull in the international financial china shop - unconcerned with the international ramifications of its actions. One of the unintended results was to substantially reduce the monetary use of silver all around the world - by draining silver from weaker nations - with great disruptive impact.
China, in particular, at a critical time in its history,
had its monetary system disrupted by the uncontrollable outflow of silver to the
U.S. Forced to abandon its silver standard, it began its disastrous experiment
with fiat money - something it probably anyway would have been forced into by the
conflicts raging within its borders. Mexico was another of the silver standard
nations adversely impacted. |
D) New Deal Failures and Successes
Rebound: |
With the restoration of the banking system, the
economy rebounded vigorously - as it always had after severe periods of banking
system suspensions and related economic contractions. |
The economy did not get back on trend. The nation did not recover its export markets until the beginning of WW-II, and New Deal command economy experiments would deliver a new blow to productivity. |
The contraction attributable to the banking holiday
crisis had been huge,
so the rebound was great. Just getting the financial system working again had to
restore a great deal of economic activity. |
Money income was still 17% below its 1929 peak. Because of the 6% population growth, per capita output, too, was still below its 1929 peak. |
The percentage increase in net national product
from the 1933 trough to the 1937 peak was 59% in constant prices - the most
rapid peacetime expansion between the Civil War and 1960. However, it was from a
very low base - such a low base that money income was still 17% below its 1929
peak. Because of the 6% population
growth, per capita output, too, was still below its 1929 peak.
The authors do not break out for us how much of the recovery was in the private economy, but do note the disproportionate concentration of the recovery in services and non-durable goods and goods "for government purchase."
The recovery was prone to relapses from the start. There
was a sharp short contraction in industrial production before the end of 1933,
another in 1934, and mild short contractions in each of the following two years. |
Labor strikes and anti-business political rhetoric further undermined the economic climate. Competition in major sectors was stifled by government cartel schemes - with inevitable declines in productivity. The impact of all this on business confidence was reflected in the disappointing net private investment numbers. |
Command economy measures inhibited and undermined
economic growth (something that became more familiar in the heyday of
command economic experiments in the 1970s). Labor costs were increased by the
National Industrial Recovery Act codes - declared unconstitutional in 1935 - and
then through the National Labor Relations Act and minimum wage laws. Payroll
taxes for social security and unemployment compensation were added in 1936 and
1937. There were tax increases on profits and a host of regulations. Some of the
regulatory schemes - such as those under the Securities Acts and Banking Acts - were quite beneficial -
providing elegant solutions to decades old problems. But the bank reforms had
serious flaws (that were not fully addressed until the end of the century). |
There was little recovery in business confidence, and investors favored the most secure and the shortest term investments. |
Savings remained idle in bank vaults for lack of loan demand by those borrowers that were perceived as suitably credit-worthy.
And there was a new substantial flow of capital
coming from abroad - fleeing political conditions in Europe. It was all more
than the still depressed economy could profitably put to work. Interest rates actually declined
during the 1933 to 1937 rebound period.
The stock of money rose 53% from the 1933 trough to the 1937 peak - closely paralleled by wholesale prices that rose 50%. The rise in the cost of living was estimated at 13%. The authors suspect the cost of living index understates the price inflation because recorded prices are more stable than the prices people actually bargain for.
The stock of money actually declined 3%
in 1937 -
an indication of the severity of the 1937 contraction. During most economic contractions,
the stock of money just slows its rate of increase.
|
This time, however, inflation was not caused by a worldwide increase in gold production but by the gold inflows from capital fleeing Europe, and was thus domestic in extent rather than worldwide. |
This was another gold inflation - as after 1900. Monetary
inflation was not caused by government expansion of the money stock. |
The deposit to bank reserve ratio fell sharply
and persistently from the 1933 economic trough to well after the start of WW-II
in Europe, as banks sought liquidity and funds were piled up in the banking system.
This reflected the continuing and worsening level of confidence within the banking
and financial community.
|
|
The substantial rise in the money stock thus was
closely related to the increase in high-powered money. |
Monetary policy:
& |
Even though monetary gold could not circulate, the
connection between the high-powered money supply and the gold inflow arose
directly. The Treasury would pay for the gold by check on a Federal Reserve
System account, but would also issue a gold certificate to the System to refill
its accounts at the System Banks. It thus acquired the gold without any budget
impact - without any decline in its accounts - and its checks increased the
money supply as they circulated and increased deposits in the banking system. |
This practice came to a temporary halt for nine months
during 1937, when the Treasury decided to pay for gold with borrowed funds -
thus "sterilizing" the gold inflow so that it did not increase
high-powered money and the money stock. This unfortunately coincided with a
period of Board tightening of bank reserve requirements and initiated a period
of tight money conditions just before the sharp 1937 economic contraction. This
sterilization program began to be unwound in September, 1937, a process that was
completed in February, 1939. |
The margin requirements on securities loans and reserve requirements for member banks were the tools the System now relied upon.
The System had shifted from "credit control" to "market control." The lack of appreciation for the importance of control of the money stock continued. |
Monetary policy at the Federal Reserve System was
shifted away from its old tools to its new tools. Federal Reserve credit
outstanding was almost constant - with not even seasonal variations - and the
discount rate remained unchanged for unprecedented lengths of time. The margin
requirements on securities loans and reserve requirements for member banks were
the tools the System now relied upon. |
Any rediscount rate above market rates is tight, even if the rate is below 2%. The unattractiveness of the rediscount facility induces banks to hold larger reserves. |
Any
rediscount rate above market rates is tight, the authors point out, even if
the rate is below 2%. The unattractiveness of the
rediscount facility induces banks to hold larger reserves. This directly
contradicts the assertions of System officials that they were maintaining
"monetary ease" to facilitate economic recovery. |
Excess reserves:
& |
Reserve
requirements for member banks could be set by the Board pursuant to
authority in the Banking Act of 1935. Margin requirements for loans for the
purchase of public
securities could be set by the Board pursuant to authority in the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934. |
Margin requirements were doubled - to 50% - in
1936 to counter inflation. They were cut to 40% in 1937 as the stock market
swooned during the 1937 contraction - and maintained at that level into WW-II. |
This was the reason for the passivity of System monetary
policy. The System didn't have to counter seasonal trends because the bank
reserves could and did absorb them. Discounting and open market purchases
couldn't help stimulate the economy because the banks already had all the loan
funds that were required and were offering it at very low interest rates. But
now in 1936, the worry was about inflation - and a stock market that was again
booming.
|
|
Since the 1937 experience, the System has often coupled its shifts in bank reserve requirements with open market operations in the opposite direction to ease the transition. The system-wide change in reserve requirements is a blunt instrument, while open market operations can be more precisely calculated. |
Bank reserve requirements were increased in August, 1936, and then twice more, in March and May, 1937 - doubling to over 25% for central reserve city banks. This coincided with the Treasury's decision to sterilize gold inflows, and practically stopped the growth of both high-powered money and the total money stock in their tracks.
Soon, banks were scrambling to restore their
"excess" reserves to levels they thought prudent during the Great Depression decade. Money stock growth was sharply reduced in the second half of
1936, peaked in March, 1937, and fell generally for the rest of the year.
Interest rates rose sharply - resulting in sharply lower bond prices that
impacted both bank reserves and the Treasury Department's funding efforts. |
The sharpness of the 1937 contraction apparently caught
the System's technical staff by surprise. It wasn't until April, 1938, that bank
reserve requirements were reduced slightly - eliminating only one-quarter of the
previous increases. However, that move came two months before the 1938 cyclical
trough.
|
|
An estimation of the time lags in the banking system
is derived from this experience. The bulk of the decline in the deposit to
reserve ratio came in just 6 weeks from January, 1934, due in large part to
large gold inflows. Treasury purchases of gold flooded the country with high-powered
money - inevitably reflected in massive increases in bank demand deposits and
bank reserves and deposits by member banks in the Federal Reserve Banks. |
The authors note the Keynesian tendency to
attribute the 1937 depression mainly to a shifting of the Federal budget from
deficit to surplus. |
|
However, the close correlation of monetary events to the peaks and troughs of the business cycle are here again stressed by the authors. Significant changes in monetary growth and decline preceded the peaks and troughs by about 2 months. "Doubtless, other factors" helped account for these business cycle movements, they acknowledge, but the restrictive monetary shifts certainly helped undermine the business climate, and the return to "rapid increase in the money stock certainly at the very least facilitated" the cyclical recovery.
|
E) Monetary Policy During World War II (1939-1948)
The WW-II period:
& |
Monetary inflation was used in part
to finance WW-II - just as in the Civil War and WW-I. The war ended in August,
1945, but wartime price inflation didn't peak until August, 1948. Wartime price
controls delayed the price inflation - but couldn't delay the loss of purchasing
power. (Indeed, price controls undoubtedly made both worse. See, "Understanding
Inflation.") |
In the 9 years from August, 1939, to August, 1948, high-powered money increased 9% per year, the stock of money increased 12.3% per year, wholesale prices increased 8.2% per year, the implicit price deflator rose 6.5% per year. Money income rose 10.5% per year and real income rose 4.2% per year.
But the totals were comparable because of the greater
length of the WW-II period. |
This was another gold inflation period. |
Lend Lease - beginning in March, 1941, marked the
financial entry of the U.S. into WW-II. Before then, Britain paid for its
supplies by draining
itself of $2 billion in gold, $234 million in dollar balances, and $335 million
in U.S. securities - mostly requisitioned from British subjects. |
Controls were imposed on consumer installment credit
under a Presidential executive order in August, 1941. The Board imposed minimum
down payment and maximum maturity restrictions for installment sales of listed
items. Durable items became unavailable after the December 7, 1941 Pearl Harbor attack,
so this
action is mostly notable because of its use after the war. It is another example
of efforts to control specific types of credit. |
"The jump in the price index on the elimination of price control in 1946 did not involve any corresponding jump in 'prices'; rather, it reflected largely the unveiling of price increases that occurred earlier." |
The cash accounts of the government budget experienced
a $10 billion deficit in 1941, nearly $40 billion in 1942, over $50 billion in
1943, over $45 billion in 1944 and over $35 billion in 1945. These sums averaged
nearly 30% of contemporary net national product. (In evaluating these sums, it
must be kept in mind that the dollar has since lost more than 90% of its value -
and the population of the nation has more than doubled.)
|
Explicit taxes financed about 48% of total federal
expenditure during WW-II. This was considerably more than in WW-I, but the
deficit was nevertheless much larger because of the larger magnitude of the
economic effort during WW-II. Of the rest, direct government money creation
financed 7%, interest bearing government securities financed 31%, and
private money issue financed 14%. |
The U.S. had not previously stiffed its creditors for its wartime expenses. Wartime inflation had been reversed after both the Civil War and WW-I.
Many "experts" expected the Great Depression to return after the war. |
Wartime inflation was probably reduced somewhat by
public post-war expectations, the authors surmise. |
The System surrendered its ability to control money. It had to create whatever fiat money was needed to maintain the fixed yield for government bills. |
Most of the increase in high-powered money and the
money stock after December 7, 1941, was
accounted for by the increase in Federal Reserve credit outstanding rather than
gold - again similar to WW-I experience. The System sold the government's bonds
- some of which it bought itself in exchange for fiat money. |
Interest rates in WW-II were lower than in WW-I -
undoubtedly explaining much of the higher rate of investment in government
securities by the non-bank public in WW-I. However, the general savings rate
during WW-II was greater - demonstrated by the lower velocity of money. Money
balances averaged 45% of one year's national income from 1914 to 1920, but 69%
from 1939 to 1948.
|
Post WW-II period:
& |
The post WW-II recession during the shift to
peacetime production was brief and not very deep. The collapse back to Great
Depression conditions confidently predicted by Marxists and Keynesians perversely
refused to materialize - like so much else of their ideological expectations. |
Price inflation then began to reflect more closely the true magnitude - the true loss of purchasing power - due to wartime inflation. |
Price inflation jumped when price controls were lifted in
1946. It then began to reflect more closely the true magnitude - the true loss of purchasing
power - due to wartime inflation. As goods became available, the velocity of
money began to recover - but the recovery was quite modest. |
The Board also made use of its other tools of monetary
policy. Margin requirements on securities purchases were increased to 100%
in January, 1946, but fell back to 75% in February, 1947, as Congress removed
this Board authority. In November, 1947, Congress removed Board authority to
regulate consumer credit - but restored it for about 10 months in August, 1948. |
|
The public expected the wartime price inflation to be reversed - as after the Civil War and WW-I. They had no historic experience with chronic inflation. The U.S. government had never stiffed its creditors to pay for its conflicts. |
Thus there is a puzzling public willingness to hold
liquid assets during a period of rapid price inflation. This is reflected in
low overall interest rates and monetary velocity that remained well below 1939
and historic levels. |
F) Monetary Policy During the Cold War (1949-1960)
Leaning against the business cycle: |
Full employment and price stability became the
responsibility of government as a result of experience with the Great Depression
and the New Deal. |
At first, it was budgetary manipulation through
changes in taxation and deficit spending - "fiscal policy" - that was
thought the primary tool. However, the budgetary process is too slow and
inflexible - and Korean War and Cold War needs soon commanded a higher priority.
Budgetary manipulation simply could not be effectively tuned to the business
cycle. |
Dissatisfaction arose because of the System's impotence in dealing with the price inflation surge during the Korean War. It could not both fix interest rates on government securities and constrain inflation. |
So, focus shifted to "monetary policy" - manipulation of the rate of growth of the money stock and efforts to administratively control interest rates. The Federal Reserve System initially was committed to support the prices - and thus limit the interest yields - of government bonds and notes as well as bills. Ultimately, the FOMC decided to limit its open market support operations to bills. Dissatisfaction arose because of the System's impotence in dealing with the price inflation surge during the Korean War. It could not both fix interest rates on government securities and constrain inflation.
System credit outstanding thus swelled by $3.5 billion in
the last half of 1950, but was offset by other factors, so money stock growth
was modest. Nevertheless, despite the tightening of reserve and margin
requirements and discount rates, wholesale price inflation soared to a 22%
annual rate in the last half of 1950. The authors attribute this mostly to a
rapid increase in the velocity of money in circulation. |
Around the world, this Keynesian theory collapsed, and nations were forced to rely on monetary restraint to curb the resulting post WW-II surges in price inflation. |
Extreme Keynesian beliefs that "money does not
matter" were undermined by the surges in price inflation after WW-II
not just in the U.S. but around the world. The Keynesians asserted that
the stock of money tended to adapt itself passively to any level of economic
activity - and that thus a low interest "cheap money" policy was
desirable. Around the world, this theory collapsed, and nations were forced to rely on monetary restraint
to curb the resulting post WW-II surges in price inflation. Their success proved that, indeed,
money matters. |
Micromanaging the economy: |
The importance of the behavior of the monetary stock
was first emphasized within the System after 1951. The authors didn't have
access to any personal papers of cognizant officials for this period, so they
had to rely on the official published documents. |
One of the criteria for monetary policy after 1951
was to restrain or sustain monetary growth at levels consistent with "the
requirements of a growing economy operating at a high level without
inflation." The System had previously been concerned "almost
exclusively with the credit aspects of its operations - - - their effects on
interest rates, availability of funds in the market, the cost and availability
of credit -- not with changes in the stock of money." These criteria were
comparatively nebulous. They also included efforts to limit the speculative use
of credit.
But mainly the System was trying to "lean against the
wind" of the business cycle - to mitigate business cycle swings. Just how to recognize
which way the "wind" would be blowing in the months ahead was not
explained. Difficulties in the timely calculation of velocity was another
complication. Knowing just how hard the System should lean was yet another
complication. "Judgment" was still at the helm. |
An accelerating and chronic outflow of gold after
1958 presented yet another unwelcome problem (that the System would be unable to
solve). Aside from noting this new problem, the authors do not discuss it.
(There is no indication in the book that at that time they realized its profound
significance.)
The recovery of velocity after WW-II was fairly sharp.
The authors assert that this "underlying trend" prevented a decline in
the money stock from causing a much sharper recession in 1948 to 1949. However,
velocity did actually decline during that recession as in most recessions during
the 20th century. |
|
The bank deposit ratios were in a sustained rise
by 1951 - especially the deposit to reserve ratio - as confidence increased and
inflation made it increasingly important to find employment for money balances.
In March, 1951, the System's obligation to support government securities prices
was terminated, and it was free to restrain monetary growth when needed.
Monetary restraint then became quite severe in response to the Korean War
inflation. |
The results of efforts to mitigate the business cycle by accelerated growth in the money stock were an acceleration of price inflation, stubbornly high rates of unemployment, and a chronic outflow of gold reserves. |
The System responded vigorously to the second
recession - resulting in a sharp increase in the money stock at the end of
1957 - and probably shortened the recession. An acceleration of consumer price
increases - to 2.3% - was one result. Another was a stubbornly high rate of
unemployment. Yet another was an outflow of gold that was becoming chronic -
shown by the book's graphs but not remarked upon by the authors. |
The 1953 to 1954 recession began a period of increasingly frantic and increasingly large discount rate swings through to the end of the period covered by the book.
The System intentionally attempted to sterilize the accelerating outflow of gold in 1958 by reductions in both the bank reserve requirements and discount rates and by a sharp increase in System credit outstanding. It thus prevented any contraction of the money stock.
During the last years covered by this history, the System monetary policy whipsawed yet once again. |
The employment of discount rate shifts had been quite
restrained after WW-II. However, the 1953 to 1954 recession began a
period of increasingly frantic and increasingly large discount rate swings through to the end
of the period covered by the book. These frequent shifts in monetary policy as
the Board undertook the task of micromanaging the economy made little overall
impact on money stock growth, although there were periodic spikes and dips. But
the Board simply couldn't satisfy its critics. It was criticized for every spike
in inflation in one direction or unemployment in the other.
|
G) The Velocity of the Money Stock (1867-1960)
Velocity: |
The trend for the "velocity" of
money had been decline from 1867 to 1941 - albeit with many spikes and
valleys associated with the business cycle and war. |
People were holding more money relative to their
income as the nation prospered. Fewer people were living hand-to-mouth, so money circulated more slowly. The
development of and growing confidence in commercial banking in which people could
conveniently hold their funds is one explanation for this trend up to the
beginning of WW-I. |
The measure of "velocity" varies with the
definition of "money." The inclusion of time deposits with currency
and demand deposits increases the amount of "money" in circulation and
thus materially reduces the magnitude calculated for its velocity. From 1952 to 1960, it
also reduces the rate of increase in velocity. Time deposits do provide an
interest yield, after all, and that yield increased as interest rates rose
during this period. |
|
In particular, expectations of economic stability are emphasized by their studies as the primary factor. Uncertainty increases the attractiveness of liquid assets - resulting in the declines in velocity during wartime and major economic contractions - while prosperity and relative stability increase the attractiveness of investment assets. As confidence in economic stability rose in the 1950s, money balances tended to decline relative to income - leading to a rise in the velocity of the money in circulation. (But the trend velocity from 1880 to 1914 - a period of massively increasing prosperity - was down.) |
H) Conclusion: The Impacts of Fluctuations in the Money Stock
Money matters: |
The many points of relationship between the changes affecting money and those affecting the economy are emphasized by the authors in their conclusion. |
|
The provision of federal insurance for bank deposits brought to an end the periodic runs and panics that had always bedeviled the U.S. banking system and money stock. This greatly smoothed the slow upwards trend in the deposit to currency ratio. Rapid declines in this ratio during periods of severe economic contraction had been creating strong downwards pressure on the total money stock as the public sought to withdraw cash from its bank deposits. Deposit insurance and confidence in the banking system seems to have had a similar smoothing influence on the deposit to reserve ratio. |
|
Resumption of the gold standard in 1879 was a political decision made possible by monetary restraint during the greenback period - but it was made possible predominantly by economic growth rather than by the laudable monetary discipline.
|
A worldwide inflation of gold supplies was the independent variable
from 1897 to 1914. Periods of gold inflation in the U.S. - driven by political
factors rather than economic factors - came at the start of both world wars. |
|
|
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2007 Dan Blatt