NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOKS
Available at Amazon.com
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 1 (1913-1951)
by
Allan H. Meltzer
Part I: The Search for Monetary Stability (1913-1923)
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 10, No. 6, 6/1/08
A) Understanding Money and Central Banking:
& |
The Federal Reserve System (the
"System") was initially designed to reduce financial instability,
improve the quality of financial services, and strengthen the payments system.
It was not intended to act as a powerful central bank. Allan H. Meltzer, in
"A History of the Federal Reserve, vol. 1 (1913-1951)," speculates
that its founders might not have supported it if they suspected it could develop
into a central bank. & |
Modern central banks control the national money supply, provide a stable but sufficiently flexible currency and a functioning payments system for money transfers and check clearance, and act as lender of last resort.
|
|
Meltzer had access to much System material that
has become available since the 1970s under the Freedom of Information Act. He
also had the active cooperation of the System. This provided him with far more
material than was available to Friedman and Schwartz for "A Monetary
History of the U.S. (1867-1960)." See,
Monetary History of U.S., Part I, "Greenbacks and Gold (1867-1921),"
Monetary
History of U.S., Part II, "Roaring Twenties Boom - Great Depression Bust
(1921-1933)" and Monetary History of
U.S., Part III, "The Age of Chronic Inflation (1933 to 1960)." & This is an absolutely essential book for anyone interested in 20th century economic history. The mass of material presented by the author is such that this review can only scratch the surface. & However, Meltzer, even more than Friedman, does tend to substantially overestimate the capabilities of monetary manipulation - modern "monetary policy." Like Friedman, this is most in evidence in his discussion of the Great Depression. (See, Meltzer, History of Federal Reserve, vol. 1, Part II, "The Engine of Deflation (1923-1933)," and Meltzer, History of Federal Reserve, vol. 1, Part III, "The Engine of Inflation (1933-1951)." & |
Typically, panics were avoided by the suspension of gold or silver payments and liberal lending to other banks on the basis of good collateral that may have been rendered temporarily illiquid due to a collapse of confidence. |
The leading central banks in 1913 were private
institutions that recognized their public responsibility to act as lender of
last resort during any banking crisis. Typically, panics were avoided by the
suspension of gold or silver payments and liberal lending to other banks on the
basis of good collateral that may have been rendered temporarily illiquid due to
a collapse of confidence. Such loans prevented good banks from being carried
away with the weaker institutions. |
There remained widespread suspicion that a central bank would sacrifice agricultural interests and regional commercial interests to those of Wall Street and the major commercial centers.
The reserve banks could lend gold to each other but there were no formal requirements for coordination or cooperation. |
Under the Federal Reserve Act of 1913, the System was a decentralized combination of public and private interests with "semi autonomous privately funded reserve banks supervised by a public board." Each region of the country wanted its own autonomous reserve bank that would take care of its own particular commercial interests. There remained widespread suspicion that a central bank would sacrifice agricultural interests and regional commercial interests to those of Wall Street and the major commercial centers.
The reserve banks could lend gold
to each other but there were no formal requirements for coordination or
cooperation. Cooperation and coordination
would have to be arranged each time the System had to act as a lender of last
resort. As privately funded institutions, the reserve banks could have conflicting
responsibilities during a crisis. |
Initially, the Federal Reserve Board (the
"Board") included the Treasury Secretary - who was its chairman -
and the Comptroller of the Currency. Even after these two officials were removed
by the 1935 Banking Act, the Treasury retained a strong influence over Board
decisions. & Under the new System, policy making authority was shared nebulously between the Board and the reserve banks - especially the influential N.Y. Federal Reserve Bank (the "N.Y. Fed"). The System was designed to assure sufficient "elasticity of currency" to avoid panics such as had occurred in 1907. One of its most important tasks was to act as lender of last resort in such a crisis. It was also expressly charged with the politically important task of providing sufficient funds to finance the movement of the fall harvest at stable interest rates. It was also (at last) intended to assure adequate supervision of its member banks, and to rediscount eligible commercial paper to facilitate commerce. & |
"Money" under the gold standard: |
The basic money supply had consisted of gold, national
bank notes, subsidiary silver and minor coin, and an assemblage of assorted
relics of earlier monetary episodes -- greenbacks from the Civil War period, silver dollars, silver
certificates, and Treasury notes of 1890. |
Federal Reserve notes could be issued by Federal Reserve Banks on the basis of a gold reserve of 40% plus 60% collateral consisting of eligible commercial paper.
When government bills were included as eligible paper, many feared the System could become an engine of inflation since new currency would not be tied to commercial needs and was just monetizing government debt. |
Now, Federal Reserve notes
were available as a part of the basic money supply. Now, deposits to the credit of banks on the books of Federal Reserve Banks were
available to satisfy legal reserve requirements and were equivalent, from the
point of view of the commercial banking system as a whole, to Federal Reserve
notes or other currency as a means of meeting demands of depositors for
cash.
|
But if the System could create money, how could it be prevented from becoming an "engine of inflation?" |
There was an immediate
impact on the money supply from the establishment of the new System. By buying and selling gold using Federal Reserve
notes, the System could change
interest rates and affect the purchasing power of money. But if the System could create money, how could it be
prevented from becoming an "engine of inflation?"
|
Money is fungible. Any credit expansion inherently expands credit for all purposes - productive, speculative and even for consumption. |
The gold standard and gold reserve requirements
were supposed to limit the amount of notes that the Federal Reserve System could
issue. Commercial rediscounting needs were supposed to provide another
limitation. The latter permitted
flexible expansion of Federal Reserve money during times of monetary stringency.
It permitted member banks to quickly increase their holdings of Federal Reserve
money by rediscounting their eligible commercial
paper - "notes, drafts, and bills of exchange arising out of actual
commercial transactions" - with a Federal Reserve Bank. |
Market pricing fluctuations and the business cycle are essential to make the gold standard work. |
However, the "real bills" doctrine was
pro-cyclical. It could accentuate the business cycle by expanding the money supply
when business was good and by contracting it when business was bad. It was the adjustment mechanisms of international trade
markets and international payments, with the cyclical price movements of domestic markets, that provided the counter-cyclical
elements. |
Interference with either international trade or the operations of the gold standard unbalanced the System in favor of either chronic deflation or chronic inflation.
Like waves in the ocean, gold always sought an equilibrium level which it could never sustain because of the persistent impacts of the financial and economic winds.
"With the growth of industrialization, labor unions, and the spread of the voting franchise, voters and governments were less willing to follow such rules in the 1920s." |
The gold standard had worked tolerably well except
during times of war when it had had to be dropped. Except during wars, inflation
rates were effectively limited by fixed gold exchange rates for national
currencies.
Discount rate adjustments were the only tool for mitigating gold flow and business cycle swings. Like waves in the ocean, gold always sought an equilibrium level which it could never sustain because of the persistent impacts of the financial and economic winds.
|
Evolution of the System: |
The financial and economic situation prior to 1913 had
been very volatile. Although overall growth was considerable, there were 6
recessions averaging about 19 months in just two decades. & |
The panic of 1907 had been particularly frightening and would have been much worse if J.P. Morgan had not personally taken on the central bank role to organize a financial rescue package.
Besides that, there were the ordinary credit needs of an economy that was still 30% agricultural, with heavy seasonal credit needs for the fall harvest. Without a central bank to discount export credits, banks in the U.S. were at a disadvantage to London banks in competing to finance agricultural exports. Politicians wanted to reduce seasonal interest rate swings and facilitate domestic financing of the nation's exports. In the 1920s, the System successfully achieved these goals and promoted financial stability - after an initial stumble in 1920-21.
|
However, times changed, and the System changed with
them. Improved communications created a national - and international -
financial market. There were wars and a vast expansion of the roles and
responsibilities of the federal government. The System originally had too many internal divisions
of authority. There were struggles for power and influence within the System and
fundamental disagreements about monetary policy and the appropriate roles of the
System both domestically and internationally. |
|
The System now issues currency backed by government securities, and as feared it has indeed become an engine of inflation.
|
B) Central Banking and Monetary Policy
Monetary theory and the
practice of monetary policy has almost from its beginnings experienced a
disconnect between short term effects and long term consequences. & |
|
David Ricardo and his followers concentrated on long
run consequences. Policies promoting the restoration and maintenance of
fixed gold exchange rates after the monetary stresses of the Napoleonic Wars
were important. See, Ricardo,
"Principles of Political Economy." |
The monetization of long term debt was resumed during the New Deal. It was permanently authorized in 1945, and the U.S. has duly experienced chronic inflation ever since.
The monetization of government securities and long term debt was resumed during the New Deal. It was permanently authorized in 1945, and the U.S. has duly experienced chronic inflation ever since. |
Henry Thornton at the turn of the 19th century
provided a unified framework for monetary policy and macroeconomic theory, but
his work was largely neglected during the 19th century until the work of 20th
century theorists Knut Wicksell, Irving Fisher, Alfred Marshall, Sir Ralph
Hawtrey, John M. Keynes and Milton Friedman. |
Thornton's contributions to central banking theory
that linked changes in money to both short and long run changes in output and
employment are summarized by Meltzer. Without this, Ricardian theory proved
useless as a practical matter for dealing with immediate monetary policy
questions. Thornton recognized that monetary expansion - at that time the
expansion of the note issue of the Bank of England - will stimulate employment
of idle economic resources, but that the increase in supply will not be enough to
prevent inflation. |
The Bank of England: |
A brief history of British banking from
the chartering of the Bank of England in 1697 until 1826 is provided by Meltzer.
The British system was rigid and thus fragile during this period. & |
The Bank of England was the only bank to receive a charter. Other banks were restricted to organizing through partnerships. They were thus small and predominantly engaged in issuing notes and discounting bills of exchange. Country banks cleared bills through correspondent London banks. As volume grew, bill brokers were used to perform part of the market clearing function. Usury law restrictions prevented the interest rate swings that could have facilitated market clearing operations.
However, bank rates were fixed at 5%, which was frequently negative - below inflation rates.
The Bank of England
thus had no means of stabilizing the market price of gold at the mint price and
maintaining convertibility. From 1790 through the Napoleonic Wars, gold reserves
sank, the pound became inconvertible in 1797, and inflation rates soared. |
Under the pressure of the Napoleonic Wars, the
Bank of England monetized vast amounts of private and government securities -
with a corresponding surge in inflation. As on
so many subsequent occasions, efforts to ration
credit - restricting discounts to "sound" commercial bills - along
with jawboning and other "qualitative" controls on
access to central bank credit - failed to stem the tide. Credit is like money and
just flows around such impediments. |
|
The Bank of England was freed from usury law
restraints in 1833 - it was
permitted to open branches - other banks were chartered as joint stock companies
with limited liability - and Bank of England notes were made legal tender. There was a flurry of changes in bank
practices that Meltzer summarizes. The Bank of England began experimenting with
its flexible bank rate as a means of controlling the basic money supply. |
With prices declining at substantial rates for much of the 19th century, especially after 1870, even a 2% nominal interest rate could be high, and 5% could be punishing. |
The problem was that economic and financial events were
dynamic, not static. Changes impacted the monetary system just as money
impacted the financial and economic system. There were wars, gold discoveries,
additional nations competing for gold reserves as they adopted the gold standard,
vast changes in international trade flows as transportation costs plummeted, and
major periodic crop failures. Financial crises afflicting trading partners
periodically washed ashore in Great Britain, and periodically there were major
domestic financial failures as might be expected in a dynamic economy.
|
During the last half of the 19th century, gold reserve
requirements were reduced. However, this meant that gold inflows permitted a
larger monetary expansion and outflows required greater monetary contractions.
The British economy thus was in a constant state of adjustment to changes in
monetary conditions. 1857, 1866, 1873, 1878 and 1890 were crisis years, although
not all of these were due to Bank policies. |
Central banking and the business cycle: |
Walter Bagehot's "Lombard
Street: A Description of the Money Market" (1873), became a classic on the
theory of monetary policy. & |
If there are both internal and external drains at the same time, interest rates must be raised because the stability of the currency is essential to all else.
Bagehot's policy prescriptions, although proven effective on numerous occasions, mean that external drains on gold reserves must be met by periods of deflation and economic decline. |
According to Bagehot, domestic crises are to be met with
a substantial volume of loans from the central bank on any good collateral. If
reserves are draining abroad, the lending rate must be raised to stop the drain.
This slows domestic economic activity and reduces imports, causes domestic
prices to decline and thus increases the competitiveness of domestic exports
which bring gold back into the country. |
There is not a single reference in Board minutes concerning the implications of real interest rates at any time during the rapid deflation from 1929 to 1933 or the rapid inflation from 1933 through the WW-II period or through most of the inflationary period of the 1970s.
When much of the System staff and policy members adopted Keynesian ideas, they "emphasized short-term or transitory effects and ignored long-term, permanent effects." |
The differences between "real" and nominal
interest rates were explained by Irving Fisher near the end of the 19th
century. His explanation was similar to but much clearer than Thornton's. The
problem is most readily resolved by maintaining stability in the purchasing
power of the currency.
Fisher also explained the relationship between inflation and unemployment and the distinction between permanent and temporary effects. When much of the System staff and many of the System policy members later adopted Keynesian ideas, they "emphasized short-term or transitory effects and ignored long-term, permanent effects."
|
The disputes over central bank monetary policy that raged throughout the 19th century are summarized by Meltzer. The Bank of England improved its abilities to offset panics, used the gold standard to prevent chronic inflation or recession, and used its discount rate to manage fluctuations in the demand for credit. However, the understanding of "monetary policy" - of its impact on long term economic trends - actually declined during the century.
Gaps and errors in monetary theory survived to afflict the Federal Reserve System. Meltzer mentions the tendency to distinguish between productive and speculative credit and "the notion that the monetary base is demand determined, an argument that has been used at times to absolve central banks of responsibility for their errors and even for their policies."
|
Deposit banking in a fractional reserve banking system served to expand the money stock because a deposit was still money that is readily available to the depositor but is also money to the borrower from the bank. |
As the payments system became more complex, the definition of
"money" and the monetary base blurred. Bills of exchange became
negotiable in an established market and banknotes increasingly
displaced specie. Deposit banking in a fractional reserve
banking system served to expand the money stock because a deposit was still
money that is readily available to the depositor but is also money to the borrower from
the bank. |
In this sea of confusion, the solid ground of central bank policy
designed to avoid domestic crises was maintenance of the exchange rate and the bank's
reserves and the maintenance of money market stability. However, central bank
control of the money market repeatedly has been cast in doubt for some analysts
because of further innovations in finance - most recently in the 1960s by
development of the eurodollar market. (Innovations with complex securitized
financial products are the current problem area.) |
|
It takes time for markets to adjust to new influences, so markets always start behind the curve and forever end overshooting the mark. |
Price fluctuations associated with the business cycle have been
a problem for central banks since the earliest times. The problem is worsened by
imperfections in market responses that create delays. It takes time for markets
to adjust to new influences, so markets always start behind the curve and forever
end overshooting the mark. Monetary policy is similarly tardy due to the time it
takes to recognize, interpret and respond to new influences. Often, this makes
monetary policies pro-cyclical instead of anti-cyclical. It was Fisher who finally
explained the links. |
C) Establishment of the System
Bank of England practices
and the theories that guided those practices were initially - in 1914 - the
predominant influences on Federal Reserve System policy. & |
|
"Monetary policy was guided by the state of the reserves, not by output, employment, or economic stability." |
Smoothing seasonal money market fluctuations and offsetting the interest rate impacts of Treasury operations were primary responsibilities. "Monetary policy was guided by the state of the reserves, not by output, employment, or economic stability."
|
The System was to furnish an elastic currency, rediscount eligible commercial paper, supervise member banks, and set discount rates "with a view of accommodating commerce and business."
The statute compromised many viewpoints with many purposes and so left them out just to get the bill passed. |
The 1913 Federal Reserve Act focused on very narrow objectives.
The System was to furnish an elastic currency, rediscount eligible commercial
paper, supervise member banks, and set discount rates "with a view of
accommodating commerce and business." Otherwise, the vast mass of research
and monetary policy alternatives considered during the legislative process seems to have had no effect. The
System was supposed to improve the management of the nation's monetary and
banking system - but there not only was intense disagreement as to how that was
to be done, the understanding of what the System was doing was deeply flawed.
|
By confining discounting to "real bills," crop movements and other commerce could be readily financed without risk of inflation.
Penalty discount rates were blunt instruments and were widely unpopular. |
Dealing with banking crises was one purpose that all agreed upon. The lender of last resort role was
widely expected of the System pursuant to the charge to provide an elastic
currency. Smoothing out seasonal credit needs, especially during the fall
harvest, was another expectation. By confining discounting to "real
bills," crop movements and other commerce could be readily financed without
risk of inflation. |
The Board was sworn into office on August 10, 1914, after a
contentious politically influenced process for establishing twelve districts and
reserve Banks. This was undoubtedly too many. Several of the reserve banks were
too small and had trouble operating efficiently. |
|
Strong viewed normal business cycle recessions as just the price that had to be paid for international financial stability and the normal international ebbs and flows of gold reserves under the gold standard. |
Benjamin Strong, first governor of the N.Y. Federal Reserve Bank (the
"N.Y. Fed") dominated monetary policy in these early years. He was a
strong proponent of fixed exchange rates, the gold standard, sound currency, and
the development of a market for bills of exchange and bankers acceptances to
displace the Wall Street short term call money market. However, the call money market
remained dominant until the New Deal.
After all, discounted commercial bills provided the income needed to
operate the System, but not many discounts would be attracted at penalty rates. The
expenses and reserve requirements of the System did not look attractive. Only 34
banks switched from state control to the System in the first 30 months of
operation. There were almost 20,000 state chartered banks. |
World War I:
& |
WW-I dominated initial experience under the System. The
international gold standard was among the first casualties of the conflict, so
there was no guide to policy. The gold standard was never restored in its
effective prewar form. & |
The gold standard was never restored in its effective prewar form. |
With a portfolio of only $65 million in government securities at the
end of 1916, the System was helpless to mitigate the inflationary impact of the
massive gold inflow from booming wartime exports. The monetary base grew at double digit
rates throughout the war. The System could not even begin to sop up some of the
excess money by selling securities. The Board tried to coordinate monetary
policy and simplify the discount rate structure among the reserve banks, but was
ignored by several of them. However, seasonal interest rate swings were
noticeably reduced. & |
When the U.S. entered the war, wartime financing needs became
predominant. The discount rate was kept at artificially low rates, so discounts
were attracted and reserve bank earnings soared - as did inflation. |
|
WW-I and its end brought economic boom and wartime inflation, a brief recession as the
economy shifted to peacetime production, an inflationary boom, and severe deflation in
quick succession. System policy only worsened these economic swings. Interest rates on war bonds
rose from 3.5% to 4.75% between May, 1917
and May, 1919. Inflation accelerated. Consumer prices rose 18% in 1918. |
The "real bills" intent of the Federal Reserve Act
was a primary casualty of the war. Collateral for issuance of Federal Reserve
notes was materially reduced, and banker's acceptances and bank promissory notes
secured by government bonds or notes became acceptable. When the U.S. entered
the war and extended financial assistance to its allies, gold inflows were
substantially reduced and System credit - mainly discounts - "became the
driving force in the expansion of the monetary base and inflation." Nearly
all the discounts in the two years from December, 1916 were secured by
government obligations.
With rates constrained below penalty levels, "direct action" programs - "moral suasion," "qualitative controls," and even the rationing of credit - were proposed. These officials "seem unaware," Meltzer points out, "that their proposals raised the cost" of the 20% of GNP needed for wartime use.
|
|
Once the credit was out the door, it inevitably increased the pool of credit available for any purpose. |
With the end of the wartime embargo on gold exports, gold began
flowing out and reserve ratios declined precipitously. The System was under
increasing financial pressure and began increasing its interest rates. Gold
reserves at the N.Y. Fed declined to just over the 40% legal minimum for the
issuance of Federal Reserve notes. |
The depression of 1920-21: |
Inflation during the WW-I period reached its peak in the second quarter of
1920 when it was soaring at a 20% annual rate. & |
All manner of speculative bubbles
were vigorously expanding, fueled by the below market discount rates that
inevitably encouraged a vast expansion of member bank borrowing from the reserve banks.
However, the stock market had already peaked and begun its decline the previous
October. Inflation and speculative excess had already reached their limits,
Meltzer asserts. & |
|
December, 1919, brought release from Treasury domination of
monetary policy. Wartime financing needs receded as the budget shifted into
substantial surplus. Several reserve banks had to rediscount with
others because their gold reserves had fallen below the 40% reserve requirement
for issuance of their Federal Reserve notes. |
Strong and Norman were determined to restore pre-WW-I gold/currency exchange rates and maintain the credit of the U.S. and England. |
Unemployment soared from 4% in 1920 to 12% in 1921. The System's industrial production index dropped 23% but recovered all lost ground by 1922. Agricultural production fell about 15%. Wholesale prices collapsed by 37% according to the later Bureau of Labor Statistics index - 44% according to a contemporary index. These were sharper declines than for any single year during the Great Depression. Yet the System did not begin to lower its interest rates until the second quarter of 1921, a year after the start of the depression. The System followed the commercial paper market, where interest rates remained high until the second quarter of 1921.
Meltzer asserts that it would have been easier to simply devalue the dollar in line with relative rates of WW-I inflation as many other nations were doing. However, U.S. policy was influenced by Strong, and policy in Great Britain was influenced by Montague Norman, the governor of the Bank of England. They were determined to restore pre-WW-I gold/currency exchange rates and maintain the credit of their nations. As after the Napoleonic Wars and the U.S. Civil War, they would not stiff their creditors to pay for the war.
|
As Strong expected, the depression was sharp but short and left the U.S. in a strong financial position for the rest of the decade. It also imposed significant deflationary pressures on the European WW-I belligerents. At the time, John M. Keynes strongly favored such conservative monetary policies.
As the new administration of Pres. Warren G. Harding took
over, Treas. Sec. Andrew Mellon joined farmers and Congress in advocating lower
System interest rates. Strong countered that until the bloated inventories of
the previous inflationary surge were worked off, a rate reduction would be
ineffective. System rates must remain at a penalty level above short term
commercial market rates to prevent the System from being used as an engine of
inflation, "with all the accompanying evils of speculation and
extravagance." (He could have been speaking about the first decade of the 21st century.)
|
By October, 1921, gold inflows had become a torrent, and the reserve
ratio at the N.Y. Fed reached 82%. Even Strong now relented and favored lower
discount rates. More than that, he favored active purchases of bankers
acceptances and even Treasury certificates to increase banking system liquidity
and to hurry commercial rates down. In November, the System's open market portfolio
began to increase. There was a threefold increase - up over $400 million - in
seven months. The uses of an activist open market policy had begun to be
recognized.
|
|
The sharp price deflation not only raised real interest rates, it also powerfully "raised the value of the public's real balances." Even though the money stock was not growing, its purchasing power was increasing sharply. |
Then, how did recovery begin? Meltzer recognizes that the sharp price deflation not only raised real interest rates, it also powerfully "raised the value of the public's real balances." Even though the money stock was not growing, its purchasing power was increasing sharply.
The author shows that despite the high real interest rates, growth in
real GNP closely followed growth in real M1 with a lag of two quarters. |
Gold sterilization and discount rate paralysis: |
Gold flows, discounting and the discount rate
were the three principle means that the System had for regulating money. & |
Money in circulation was to increase and decrease and interest
rates were to rise and fall with gold flows. Member banks presented or paid off
"real bills" at the given discount rate at their discretion. These
transactions were in Federal Reserve Bank notes, a component of the monetary base which
- other things being equal - expanded when the notes flowed out of the System and
contracted when the notes flowed into the System. The discount rate was supposed to
be a penalty rate that responded to market rates in a way that prevented the
System from becoming an engine of inflation. |
By any measure, the System had flunked its first test - making matters worse instead of improving on the automatic gold standard market mechanism. |
If the System had followed the gold standard rule and reduced
its interest rates in response to the gold inflows, those inflows would have
moderated or reversed, facilitating the efforts of Great Britain and other
European WW-I belligerents to get back on the gold standard as well as
mitigating the domestic depression.
|
Price stability would be advocated as a guide by many monetary
authorities and theorists for many years to
come. However, a price stability standard opened the System to political
pressure to act when prices fluctuated for reasons unrelated to monetary
developments. The public would not distinguish between relative and absolute
price changes. Strong forcefully opposed this policy. Price stability was a desirable
outcome of policy but not a guide. Strong thus favored the reconstruction of the
international gold standard. |
|
One problem with the penalty rate requirement was that the System accepted a wide variety of commercial and government securities with a wide risk spectrum as collateral for discounting. Each type had different market interest rates. The Bank of England accepted only real bills - commercial bills of exchange - with a well defined market rate. The U.S. financial system was simply too diverse in financial, economic and geographic terms.
|
D) Conclusion
System limits and achievements:
& |
Strong changed his views
about discount policy as a result of the 1920-21 depression. Member banks chose whatever eligible paper was convenient
to offer for discount at a reserve bank. The funds obtained from the System
entered member bank reserve pools, and there was no way to distinguish among the
variety of loans made by the member banks whether reserve bank funds were used
for commercial or speculative loans. Nor did it matter for this purpose whether the eligible
paper discounted was government securities or commercial bills of exchange.
Money is fungible. & |
There were successes during this period. There was no panic despite a
rate of bank failures that exceeded the rates in 1893, 1907 and 1908. The System
successfully pooled its gold reserves to make interdistrict loans to those
reserve banks that experienced unacceptably low gold reserve ratios. The system
for issuing currency was improved, seasonal swings in currency demand were
accommodated, and a market in banker's acceptances was supported. A market in "federal funds" developed principally operating through
the N.Y. Fed that enabled member banks with excess
reserves to make them available overnight or for a bit longer to banks with
deficient reserves. |
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2008 Dan Blatt