A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. II,
(1951-1986)
by
Allan H. Meltzer
Part IV: Conflicting Objectives (1951-1960)
Page Contents
FUTURECASTS online magazine
www.futurecasts.com
Vol. 12, No. 4, 4/1/10
N) The Modern Federal Reserve System
Independence: & |
That Federal Reserve System independence
is at best greatly limited is emphasized repeatedly by Allan H. Meltzer in "A History of the Federal Reserve, Volume
2 (1951-1986)." |
As the Federal Reserve System regained some measure of independence under the Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord of March, 1951, See, Meltzer, History of Federal Reserve, vol. 1, (1913-1951) Part III, "The Engine of Inflation (1933-1951)," it found its policy options severely constrained by the 1946 Employment Act.
|
The System interpreted its role as primarily concerned with the domestic financial system and economy, leaving exchange rate and international concerns to the Treasury with which it cooperated. Inflation was interpreted as a secondary concern. Congressional pressure made this interpretation unavoidable.
Many administration, congressional and even System officials viewed monetary policy as playing a supporting role in financing budget deficits and restraining interest rate increases. Sustaining the purchasing power of the dollar was viewed as a highly desirable but definitely subsidiary objective.
It was thus Congress, not the monetary authority, that determined the extent of the inflation and financial instability suffered by the nation in the 1970s. |
Freed from direct wartime subservience to the Treasury, the Federal Reserve System (the "System") still understood that it was obligated to support congressional and administration policies and assure the success of Treasury financing and refinancing operations. The System interpreted its role as primarily concerned with the domestic financial system and economy, leaving exchange rate and international concerns to the Treasury with which it cooperated. Inflation was viewed as a secondary concern. Congressional pressure made this interpretation unavoidable.
The System is, after all, just a creature of Congress and lived in fear that Congress would reduce even the limited independence that it had for the conduct of monetary policy. Many administration, congressional and even System officials viewed monetary policy as playing a supporting role in financing budget deficits and restraining interest rate increases. Sustaining the purchasing power of the dollar was viewed as a highly desirable but definitely subsidiary objective.
The existence of substantial budget deficits beginning in the 1960s and political pressure to maintain low interest rates thus tied the System's hands in its losing fight to restrain price inflation. It was thus Congress, not the monetary authority, that determined the extent of the inflation and financial instability suffered by the nation in the 1970s. Nevertheless, when there was public and political support for the fight against inflation in the 1980s, the System was able to make the hard austerity decisions needed to triumph over inflation.
|
The System did, however, have financial independence. It was
not subject to the congressional
appropriations process. It was still
a banking organization with a paid in capital from its member banks. Its
substantial income from its large portfolio of securities and commercial paper
was far more than required to cover its operating and administrative expenses. This shielded it somewhat from political
pressure, much to the continuing chagrin of populists. |
The U.S. held almost $25 billion in gold in 1949.
This was about two thirds of the world's non-Soviet monetary gold. |
|
The Bretton Woods exchange rate structure was proving tremendously successful in restoring economic prosperity throughout the advanced economic world, but it was actually inherently incompatible with the U.S. government's impossible full employment obligations under the 1946 Employment Act. |
Under the Bretton Woods agreements, the dollar was the principal reserve currency and the pound a
secondary reserve currency. Other nations held their exchange rates within a 1%
band on each side of its dollar parity. France and Canada were the main floating
exchange rate nations. The dollar was convertible into gold on the major
international gold markets at $35 per ounce. The IMF could provide loans to nations having a temporary payments imbalance. |
During a period of increasing inflationary instability, rigid systems like fixed exchange rates become impossible, regardless of their benefits under non-inflationary policies.
The U.S. would have to sacrifice price stability and fixed exchange rates to retain currency convertibility, free international capital flows and pursuit of permanent full employment. |
Milton Friedman began explaining this incompatibility as early as 1950. During a period of increasing inflationary instability, rigid systems like fixed exchange rates become impossible, regardless of their benefits under non-inflationary policies. By the end of the decade, this incompatibility was recognized by many others. System staff member Woodlief Thomas explained that the gold outflow was chronic and could not be controlled as long as monetary and fiscal expansion were used in the equally doomed effort to achieve sustained full employment.
However, Congress remained intentionally,
determinedly ignorant. The U.S. would have to sacrifice price stability and
fixed exchange rates to retain currency convertibility, free international
capital flows and continuation of its impossible pursuit of permanent full
employment levels. In 1958, the System's Federal Open Market Committee
(the " FOMC") began to include the balance of
payments, the U.S. competitive position and gold losses in its regular
congressional briefings, but it was paralyzed by domestic political
considerations and could make no effective response. |
The major weakness of all fixed exchange rate systems is the lack of an adjustment mechanism. When adjustments become necessary, they arrive suddenly in the form of a financial crisis. Nations - like the U.S. and Great Britain - that do not accept monetary and budget discipline must suffer currency devaluations that come suddenly during repeated financial crises, or give up the substantial commercial benefits of a fixed exchange rate. Even the minor level of inflation accepted after WW-II proved ultimately incompatible with fixed exchange rates.
Meltzer favors a floating gold price rising at a rate governed by
expanding trade or by a price index instead of floating exchange rates. After
all, $35 gold had lost 25% of its purchasing power between 1946 and 1960. (This
is another administered policy alternative that is much easier in contemplation
than it would be in practice.) |
The engine of inflation:
& |
Monetary
policy operations under Bretton Woods were initially restricted to Treasury
securities - mainly bills - and gold or gold
certificates and foreign exchange. Depositary institutions could borrow from the
System on the basis of short term commercial paper or Treasury bills that the
System could simply allow to run off if it wanted to reduce its monetary
position. |
Congress and many administration officials began to view the System as a source of funding for their programs. |
The System was increasingly viewed as a source of funds for
administration and congressional programs. This was perhaps inevitable and
precisely as feared by the founders of the System.
Monetary inflation above target levels is never reversed. Since the end of WW-II, it has simply been accepted as the base from which subsequent monetary targets are set.
|
Free reserves - reserves in excess both of reserve level requirements and member borrowing from the System - were both indicator and target. The System account manager operating through the New York Federal Reserve Bank (the "N.Y. Fed") monetary trading desk, attempted to control free reserves within a margin of plus or minus $100 million. However, the distribution of free reserves between country and city banks could shift in meaningful ways not accounted for by the aggregate figure.
|
|
Policy difficulties were explained by the FOMC staff. Meltzer summarizes their explanation.
By 1960, the use of free reserves as a target was widely viewed as unsatisfactory.
Further complications arose from a policy decision in November 1960,
when the
Board permitted banks to include vault cash in their reserves. That became a
game changer in the 1980s when large amounts of "vault cash" was
increasingly being kept in ATM machines.
|
Monetary aggregates, exchange rates, price inflation, financial market stability, and the strength of the economic expansion were all among the System's primary concerns.
Vital statistical measures of productivity and output growth are very inexact and are major causes of the unreliability of economic and inflation econometric forecasts. Indeed, price inflation in those days was probably overstated because the inflation indexes did not consider quality changes and new product introductions. |
By the 1980s, the Board was mixing a whole bunch of objectives, with
sometimes greater emphasis on one or another, leaving observers and market
participants befuddled and uncertain. Monetary aggregates, exchange rates, price
inflation, financial market stability, and the strength of the economic
expansion were all among its primary concerns. Indeed, by the 1990s, no major
central bank was following a disciplined rule. |
Throughout the period covered in this book, as before, business contractions continued to follow declining real base growth rates. |
Monetary policy was shifted to control of monetary aggregates in the 1980s by Chairman Paul Volcker. He understood that chronic inflation was always a monetary phenomenon. However, there was increasing uncertainty as to just what the monetary aggregates were.
Real - inflation adjusted - monetary base growth rates are the
indicator and monetary policy target favored by Meltzer. Throughout the period covered in this book, as before, business contractions continued to follow declining real
monetary base growth rates. Inflation followed increases in base growth rates that were
sustained. Meltzer emphasizes that the monetary base was actually more accurately correlated with both
economic contractions and price inflation than was real interest rates, another
of Meltzer's favorite indicators. |
& |
The Keynesian conceit concerning
government ability to suppress the business cycle supported passage of the
Employment Act of 1946. Although not explicitly stated, the legislation was
viewed as a commitment "to maintain economic conditions consistent with
full employment." (The government might as well have committed itself to
prevent the incoming tide.) |
The System had to monetize enough debt to prevent interest rates rising to constraining levels. This transformed the System into an enabler of the growing Keynesian deficits and the price inflation of the 1960s and 1970s. |
Congress had accepted responsibility for maintaining "full
employment," soon interpreted as a rate of 4% unemployment. It put considerable
pressure on the System and the administration to sustain that level. Chairman
Martin's rhetoric supported anti-inflation policies and System
independence, but he nevertheless viewed the System as obligated to support
Treasury financing and respond to congressional and administration policies.
|
A low inflation rate is a precondition for achieving and sustaining low unemployment levels. |
Low inflation was recognized as of equal importance with low unemployment during the three decades beginning in 1980. As Meltzer points out, a low inflation rate is actually a precondition for achieving and sustaining low unemployment levels. Except in the short run - which can be very short indeed - there is no tradeoff between unemployment and price inflation.
|
The simplistic Keynesian assumptions of
the post-WW-II period are summarized by Meltzer. In the late 1960s, the "Phillips Curve"
assumption that there was a natural tradeoff between inflation and unemployment
was added to account for the persistence of price inflation. |
|
The Phillips Curve itself was obviously flawed. It was derived
from experience during the period when a dollar-gold exchange standard anchored the
purchasing power of the dollar and thus limited price inflation and inflationary
expectations. Keynesian policies dependent on this "Phillips Curve"
tradeoff were doomed to failure as soon as the dollar-gold exchange standard was
abandoned.. (To this day, many Keynesians remain stupidly in denial that their
only period of apparent success, during the 1960s, is attributable solely to the
"barbaric metal.") |
Monetarists, led by Milton Friedman, soon launched a
counterattack. Money matters, they insisted. They supported a classical view of
the relationship between money and asset prices, commodity prices and exchange
rates. See three articles beginning with Friedman & Schwartz,
"Monetary History of U.S., Part I, "Greenbacks and Gold
(1867-1921).".
Their policies in ruins by the end of the 1970s, the Keynesians have conceded the validity of most monetarist positions.
|
|
Monetarists recognize market resiliency and its capacity for appropriate adjustments. They recognize that governments can nudge markets towards equilibrium, but fear that government policy errors will over-correct and thus just cause increased instability. |
Monetarists favor monetary policy constrained by rules such as the gold standard or bimetallism or some other commodity standard. They recognize market resiliency and its capacity for appropriate adjustments. They recognize that governments can nudge markets towards equilibrium, but fear that government policy errors will over-correct and thus just cause increased instability. Keynesians assert that discretionary authority is essential so that monetary policy can support budget deficits and play a lead role in stabilizing the economy.
Ah, but there are devils in the details, as 90 years of System history and a record full of major mistakes amply demonstrates. Friedman and others began emphasizing weaknesses in the statistics that often misled the policymaking efforts of the System's Board of Governors (the " Board") as well as theoretical misunderstandings of ultimate impacts of monetary manipulation. "Until 1944, monetary policy was typically procyclical until late in the inflation or recession." Rational expectations within the markets could develop in ways that would lead to responses that the Keynesians could not account for.
|
Rational expectations econometric models add important factors to the simplistic Keynesian models - but still fail to reflect reality sufficiently to be reliable guides to policy. No central bank relies on them. |
Rational expectations econometric models are now used by the System staff. These models add important factors to the simplistic Keynesian models - but still fail to reflect reality sufficiently to be reliable guides to policy. No central bank relies on them. See, Hendry & Ericsson, "Understanding Economic Forecasts" There are costs to acquiring the information required, and interpretation of the pertinent information may be uncertain. There are vast uncertainties in the statistics. The pace of productivity growth, for example, is never precisely known. The very process of aggregation destroys vital information about the structure of the aggregates relied upon by the econometric models. Vital aspects of the economy cannot be modeled. They cannot be expressed as an equation.
Long term expectations forecasts are very unreliable. What will the
shape of the yield curve be? How will exchange rates fluctuate? For these and
many other reasons, macroeconomic models routinely fail to accurately forecast
inflation rates or business cycle swings - which happen to be the type of
information needed for monetary efforts to stabilize the economy. Despite the increasing sophistication and professional training of
the Board members and their chairmen since 1970, "analytical errors and
misjudgments had a large role in mistaken policy choices." |
Meltzer summarizes other disputes within the economics profession.
|
Monetary manipulation is now the primary weapon for economic stabilization. Fiscal policy - budget deficits - are now recognized as relatively ineffective in combating recessions. (Of course, the politicians do love to spend the money and posture as the saviors of jobs.) However, monetary policy has proven far more difficult in practice than in the simplistic rationalizations of academic and intellectual theorists. Monetary policy has frequently proved to be procyclical instead of countercyclical during the initial stages of business cycle swings. Thus, the disputes over the best monetary policy techniques rage on.
Misinterpretation of short term interest rate fluctuations was one of the primary reasons for the procyclical impacts of monetary policy.
|
|
The System monetized increasing amounts of the federal budget debt.
From about 9% in the 1950s, this rose sharply after 1964 to almost 17% of
massively increasing deficits in 1973-1974 and then declined back to about 9% of
the even more massively increased federal deficits in 1986.
|
O) The Eisenhower Administration
Personnel and procedures:
& |
William McChesney Martin,
Jr., became chairman of the Board of Governors in April, 1951, and served
until January, 1970. His father had been a chairman and Reserve Bank governor
between 1914 and 1941. Two of the most influential staff members when Martin
took office, Winfield Riefler and Woodlief Thomas, had served in the System in
the 1920s and 1930s. |
Martin paid no heed to economic theory, and began as during his father's time employing member bank borrowed reserves under the Riefler rule as a primary guide to policy. $500 million was still considered the neutral level, although there had been about a 50% price inflation due to WW-II. The 1923 Tenth Annual Report remained the primary guide to policy. See, Meltzer, History of Federal Reserve, vol. I, (1913-1951) Part II, "The Engine of Deflation (1923-1933)" at segment on "Gold sterilization."
Unfortunately, the statistics on member bank reserves had many ambiguities, such as seasonal adjustments, projections of Treasury deposits, and distinctions between temporary and persistent changes. The Board's calculations frequently differed from those of the N.Y. Fed. Unfortunately, at any level of free reserves or borrowing, "policy could be lax or restrictive depending on what happened to the growth of money or credit."
|
Martin made major changes in System operations, further diminishing the role of the N.Y. Fed and concentrating policy making in the FOMC in Washington, where monetary policy was increasingly subjected to political pressure. He increased FOMC influence over the manager of the System Open Market Account. The manager was chosen by the N.Y. Fed and executed monetary policy at the N.Y. Fed money market trading desk in accordance with FOMC directives but under N.Y. Fed supervision..
The five member Executive Committee that had executed
monetary policy between the previously infrequent FOMC meetings had been
presided over and dominated by the president of the N.Y. Fed due to his greater
expertise and knowledge of money market conditions. By requiring all members of
the FOMC to state their opinions and recommendations before hearing from the
N.Y. Fed president, Martin forced them to develop pertinent expertise with which to
counter N.Y. Fed influence. |
|
The discretionary authority of the N.Y. Fed trading desk
was temporarily limited when open market purchases were restricted to Treasury
bills. However, the FOMC provided the manager of the System Open Market Account only general,
remarkably imprecise guidance. Typical FOMC directives might call for
"monetary ease" or "monetary restraint" to achieve
"sustainable growth - - - without inflation." The manager thus
retained considerable discretion, and often was able to switch monetary policy
emphasis before the FOMC could get around to revising the language in its
directives. Both Martin and Sproul undoubtedly had considerable influence on the
manager. They resisted suggestions for more explicit directives that might
limit the manager's discretion.
|
By the 1960s, reducing unemployment had become the System's primary concern. |
Stabilization policy became increasingly important
not only because of Keynesian assertions about the capabilities of fiscal and
monetary policy but also because of public fear of a return of the Great
Depression and public expectations about government responsibility for
prosperity and employment levels. Chairman Martin was quickly included in
regular conferences with administration economic policy officials where he was
increasingly subjected to political influence. |
Complicating matters were the System's inadequate monetary policy tools.
|
Thus, there was price inflation in the 1950s - for
the first time in U.S. peacetime history. While only a few percent on average,
efforts to control it led to mild recessions in 1953-1954, 1956-1957, and
1960-1961 during a hotly contested presidential election. |
|
Regulatory efforts to control credit for consumer
durables - Regulation W - and real estate - Regulation X - as well as price and
wage controls were tried during the Korean War and quickly proved unenforceable.
The Korean War ended in June, 1953. Eisenhower ended the control efforts and the
experience made the System an opponent of all further efforts of this kind. The
regulators were simply no match for the ingenuity of private entities and their
lawyers in working around the regulations. |
& |
The 1950s were generally
prosperous, with real GNP rising at a 2.6% compound annual rate. However,
the trends were downhill. Although varying with the business cycle, unemployment
levels and budget deficits were getting worse and the dollar was weakening as
the decade progressed. |
Discounts were increasingly collateralized with Treasury bills, and open market purchases of Treasury bills were increasingly used to inject cash reserves into the banking system and support Treasury financing operations. The "real bills" doctrine of the 1920s faded away and - as feared by the founders of the System - the System did indeed become an engine of inflation. |
Price inflation, too, was worsening until the
1957-1958 recession. Price inflation averaged 2.5%, but hit 5% in 1957. Thus, interest rates,
too, were rising, A Treasury note yielded 5% by the end of the decade - the
highest yield since formation of the System. The markets were beginning to
expect price
inflation to be a persistent presence. |
The bills only policy was formally revoked in 1961, as personnel changes increased Keynesian influence within the System.
In practice, few long term securities were purchased until the Credit Crunch recession in 2008 when more than half the System's portfolio quickly came to consist of longer term issues. |
The FOMC got out of the business of intervening in
long term bond markets for awhile on March 4, 1953, when it restricted its
open market operations - except during moments of disorderly markets - to short
term Treasury bills. For longer term issues, the markets were free to set
prices. System intervention had in fact proven to be a disruptive influence in
the price discovery functioning of the markets. |
By 1956, the federal funds interest rate had displaced the Treasury bill rate as the primary short term interest rate indicator and System interest rate policy target. |
The federal funds market was a
new and very useful development. The vast increase in government short
term debt provided a new mechanism for banks to manage their reserves and for
System open market operations. |
Monetary policy operations:
& |
Market interest rates rose
substantially above the discount rate in the 1952-1953 period. It became a
no-brainer for member banks to borrow from the System not just to meet short
term liquidity needs but for an easy profit. Discount borrowing surged above $1
billion in 1952, but the System persisted in interpreting this as a tight money
condition - as evidence of financial system distress - despite a surge in base
money growth. |
The System stumbled into the 1953-1954 recession
still misinterpreting the impacts of member bank borrowing levels and free
reserve levels, and still failing to distinguish between real and nominal
interest rates. Meltzer points out that real - inflation adjusted - base money growth rates -
ignored by the System - provided the best indicator of events. They
declined four months before the recession and rose a couple of months before it
ended.
|
Recovery was vigorous well into 1955. Modest
levels of deflation did not seem to hinder economic growth. (They never do!) The
System's indicators remained steady in 1956. Member borrowing remained between
$700 million and $800 million. Monetary base growth remained around 1%. Federal
funds rates rose but stayed below 3% throughout the final quarter. Nominal GNP
nevertheless rose 5.5%, so the monetary aggregates had to support an increasing
level of economic
activity. |
|
Martin was prophetically pessimistic about the political will to restore lost purchasing power once lost to inflation.
Discount rate changes were becoming increasingly frequent - and contentious - as stabilization efforts perversely created increasing instability. |
The U.S. had never suffered price
inflation in peacetime before this time, and Martin was especially concerned about it. He was
prophetically pessimistic about the political will to restore purchasing
power once it was lost to inflation. Meltzer provides considerable detail about the
uncertainty and conflicting opinions of the Board and FOMC members as they wrestled
meeting after meeting seeking a discount rate and open market policy that might be adequate to
control inflation yet avoid the ire of congressional critics. Many factors were
considered, but still not the ebb and flow of the monetary aggregates. |
Like so many others, including recent efforts to allocate financial assets into the housing market, the Regulation Q government effort to allocate financial assets ended badly. It "began the process that culminated in the massive losses by savings and loan insurance systems in the 1980s." |
Regulation Q controls became a casualty of the rising
inflation and interest rates. Regulation Q established the maximum interest
rate that could be paid for time and savings deposits. The rate had been set at
2.5% since 1936, but now short term interest rates were around 3%. Banks adopted
numerous circumventions involving "free" services to retain
depositors.
There were heated debates within the Board
and its staff. Deposits were draining away from regulated banks. By December,
1956, the Board surrendered and increased Regulation Q to 3%. There was also a
4.25% ceiling on Liberty Bonds and subsequent bonds with five or more years to
maturity that also bumped up against rising market rates. This forced the
Treasury to finance with shorter term securities. During the 1950s, the average maturity of the
growing federal debt dropped about 2 years to a new level of 4 years and 4 months. Refinancing became considerably more expensive.
The bond interest rate ceiling was finally
lifted in 1960. |
The recession of 1957-1958:
& |
Generally prosperous conditions continued through the first three quarters of 1957, with no remarkable shifts in the prominent indicators - except for price inflation. Both the CPI and deflator indexes rose to a 3.75% average rate.
|
The Board raised the discount rate and sold government
securities to drain some money from member banks. This forced them to
increase their borrowing at the higher discount rate. The manager of the trading
desk was being wrong-footed by temporary surges and retreats of financial and
economic indicators. |
By its administered efforts to stabilize the economy, the System was encouraging the increase in leverage that must inevitably increase instability. |
The advent and permanence of "creeping
inflation" was by this time recognized by the Board. The markets now
expected permanent and even increasing inflation levels, reflected in
permanently higher long term interest rates. Monetary inflation had "validated"
WW-II and Korean War price increases, and the System had responded to the
1953-1954 recession with a surge of monetary inflation that was not thereafter
unwound. |
The discount rate was increased to 3 .5% in August, 1957, after a Treasury financing was completed. This was the peak of the economic expansion. The whole exercise had an eerie similarity to the August 1929 discount rate hike.
Meltzer concludes that monetary policy was again procyclical
|
There were prescient fears that if the recession ended too soon, it would not bring down inflation rates, the higher prices would become entrenched and the next price surge would ratchet up from that point. |
The 1957-1958 recession was short - calculated at
8 months - but fairly sharp. Unemployment hit 7.5%, considerably higher than in
the 1953-1954 recession. A substantial budget deficit was employed by the
Eisenhower administration to combat the recession, but the vast majority of it
was spent after recovery had already begun. The administration thus credited the
natural resiliency of the nation's free economy for the recovery, a belief that the
increasingly influential Keynesians denigrated.
|
The recovery was robust but short. Both the Board
and the Eisenhower administration shifted swiftly to containing inflation. |
The Federal Reserve could maintain low inflation -- or price stability -- despite large government spending and deficits, despite frequent periods of even keel [support for Treasury financings], and despite its contrary belief. It had to be willing to allow market interest rates to increase in the face of criticisms, even mounting criticisms, in the Congress and elsewhere.
The free reserves target and indicator did not reflect the monetary aggregates factors. |
Recovery remained strong through October 1959, despite a steel strike. Price inflation and growth of the monetary aggregates remained very low despite Board and widespread financial system fears. Market interest rates were rising in response to surging credit demand. This was reflected in the rising monetary velocity calculation. Bank loans increased at a 10.3% annual rate during the two year expansion.
Worries about the monetary aggregates surfaced within the
FOMC in January 1960. The slow to negligible growth of base money and M1
for several years was noted with alarm by two of the Regional Bank presidents.
The slow growth of the money aggregates had been overcome by increasing factors
of velocity, but that could not continue. The banking system was getting
dangerously overextended. |
The peak of the expansion and the start of the
next contraction came inconveniently for Richard Nixon in April 1960. The
decline in the growth of the monetary base to an annual rate of just ¼%
provided an accurate monetarist indicator. Rising free reserves provided the
FOMC with an inaccurate indicator. Closer examination indicates that the rise in
free reserves resulted from a decline in member bank borrowing which was a
typical result when the federal funds rate declined to or below the level of the
discount rate. It had nothing to do with monetary policy ease. FOMC staff forecasts of
continued economic expansion thus proved false. |
|
Administered stabilization efforts were clearly increasing instability. Three recessions in eight years and 19 changes in the discount rate left the System exposed to criticism. |
Nevertheless, the System - and the money markets -
were being whipsawed by the increasingly frantic FOMC efforts to stabilize
the markets. These interest rate and business cycle fluctuations were
unprecedented in their rapidity. Administered stabilization efforts were clearly
increasing instability. Three recessions in eight years and 19 changes in the
discount rate left the System exposed to criticism as the Keynesians gained
predominant influence under the Kennedy/Johnson administration. |
P) Conclusion
A deeply flawed administered alternative:
& |
Martin had succeeded in centralizing control of
monetary policy in the FOMC by the end of the 1950s. Sproul was no longer
president of the N.Y. Fed. The twelve Reserve Banks still sent requests for
discount rate changes to the Board of Governors, but it was the FOMC - with its
majority of all seven Board governors and minority of five Reserve Bank
representatives - usually the presidents - that made the main decision to be
sent to the Board for ratification. The seven Board governors were appointed by
the president with Senate approval. Open market operations were the main policy
instrument. |
Martin's practice was to gain consensus for decisions. He had little trouble during the 1950s, but faced increasing difficulty with the Keynesian appointees of the Kennedy/Johnson administration. He took his anti-inflation role seriously and viewed himself and the System as the only entities in government concerned with maintaining the purchasing power of the dollar. However, he understood that the fight against inflation had to be secondary to cooperation with administration and congressional policies expressed in the budget.
The board recognized that its various monetary tools were often in conflict with one another. It continued with attempts to discourage extended borrowing from the System and recognized the need for high discount rates to control borrowing.
|
There were several weaknesses that still afflicted
System monetary analyses, as pointed out above. The
FOMC and the N.Y. Fed recognized the lack of precision of the free reserves
target policy. The System used free reserves as a
policy target so it could deflect political criticism by blaming the markets for
rising interest rates. Even Paul Volcker during his harsh austerity campaign against price
inflation in 1979-1982 sought to "avoid some
criticism by attributing the rise in interest rates to market forces"
rather than System policy. |
|
At least "Martin avoided the bad advice that the economic models of the period urged on the FOMC." |
Staff analyses during the 1950s finally recognized that
price levels fluctuated for many reasons but that chronic price inflation was
possible only with excessive growth in the money supply. Precise calculation of
appropriate rates of money growth were not attempted or thought desirable, but
it was concluded that long term money growth should equal long term economic
growth rates and should wax and wane against rather than with the business cycle
to counter procyclical fluctuations in credit. |
"Operations were more a matter of guess or judgment and trial and error." Policy responses to changing conditions were frequently delayed as the FOMC awaited clarifying developments. The statistics were uncertain and frequently took weeks and months to reflect what was happening. |
The wide variety of theories advocated - most of them
clearly wrong - led Chairman Martin and many other FOMC members to distrust
theory in favor of short term responses to actual market conditions - which
themselves could be devilishly hard to interpret. "Operations were more a
matter of guess or judgment and trial and error." Policy responses to
changing conditions were frequently delayed as the FOMC awaited clarifying
developments. The statistics were uncertain and frequently took weeks and months
to reflect what was happening. |
Martin and the Board concentrated on the short term - the
very short term - conditions in the money markets. They concentrated on maintaining stability and
adequate but not excessive availability of credit. They avoided forecasts or
policies that looked further ahead than just a few weeks.
|
Meltzer discusses the constant analytical ferment within the System. Analysis was constrained by awareness of the political constraints on the actions of the "independent" System. The System was relying on imprecise and relatively ineffective policy tools with which it struggled to achieve its monetary policy objectives. There were overt efforts by administrations - from Truman to Nixon - to pressure Board chairmen to loosen monetary policy. Melzer provides a brief summary.
In short, "independence" only extended to protection against narrow partisan influence. Broader economic policies reflected in the budgets and their deficits had to be supported. The System could not prevent price inflation if the government ran large deficits and insisted on low interest rates. The primary responsibility of a central bank - to maintain the purchasing power of the currency - had to be sacrificed whenever there were large continuous budget deficits that could only be prevented from pushing interest rates up to constraining levels if the monetary authority monetized large amounts of the debt. Board chairmen thus became frequent advocates for the reduction of federal deficits.
|
|
In Germany, reinforced by powerful popular opposition to price inflation as a result of the experience of the 1920s, Bundesbank independence was sufficient to resist political pressure. (Germany also rejected Keynesian policies and thus Germany thrived as the economic and financial powerhouse of Europe.)
|
Keynesian criticism:
& |
Keynesians viewed the Eisenhower
years with disdain. Meltzer views the 1950s as the second
most successful decade for the System after the 1920s, even though the growth
rate was less than the nation's 3% historic average. Growth averaged 2.7% per year between 1954 and 1959 and
the GNP deflator rose only 2.25% per year. |
However, the Keynesians asserted that growth rates in
excess of 4% could have been achieved if an increased rate of monetary
growth had been permitted and price inflation had not been so rigidly
constrained. Many had absurd faith in credit, price, wage and interest rate controls. They claimed there was no real connection between monetary
inflation and price inflation. The real changes occurred in "velocity"
- in the complex financial system - and in factors such as "cost push"
or "wage push" inflation. They assumed that such factors impact
general price levels regardless of whether monetary expansion ratified the
higher prices. They believed that their Keynesian policies could avoid business cycle
contractions and thus retain high rates of economic growth. They provided
confident assurances that their policies could deal with price inflation. |
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.
Copyright © 2010 Dan Blatt