NOTICE: FUTURECASTS BOOKS
Available at Amazon in
hard cover, soft cover, ebook
"Understanding the Economic Basics &
Modern Capitalism: Market Mechanisms and Administered
Alternatives" Smith:
Wealth of Nations. Ricardo: Principles.
|
FUTURECASTS JOURNAL
Capitalism:
Its Origins and Evolution as a System of Governance
by
Bruce R. Scott
Page Contents
February, 2013
www.futurecasts.com
Part I: The Concept of Capitalism
Describing the elephant:
& |
So, what is
"capitalism," anyway? For two centuries, whole library shelves
have been filled with efforts to answer that question. However, there is little
confidence in the answers. There is always evidently so much left unexplained.
Theorists resemble at best the blind men describing the elephant by the part
they find themselves examining. |
|
The focus is too narrow. It inevitably leaves out much of the rest of the elephant.
Economic analysts must step back and open their eyes to view substantially more of the elephant.
Only with the broader interdisciplinary scope of political economy can valid explanations be developed for such vital phenomena as economic growth or decline, the business cycle, the underperformance of many social democratic economic systems, and the many failures of economic development policy.
Both political and economic systems must be robust enough to function with imperfect men and women achieving imperfect results at all levels. There are strong natural incentives that create constant threats to the proper functioning of both spheres and require constant effort at containment. At any moment, they must be a part of any valid economic analysis. |
In "The Concept of Capitalism," Bruce R.
Scott of the Harvard Business School demonstrated conclusively one major
shortcoming of most efforts. The focus is too narrow. It inevitably leaves
out much of the rest of the elephant. This short - 75 page - monograph was the
author's summary of a much larger work, "Capitalism: Its Origins and
Evolution as a System of Governance," recently published.
As might be expected, the author and FUTURECASTS have some agreements and some disagreements on these issues. FUTURECASTS readers are encouraged to add their input. E-mail comments to blat1@futurecasts.com.
Adam Smith provided an elegant description of the
functioning and capabilities of markets and the ways unwise government policies
undermined those capabilities. See, Smith, "The Wealth of Nations," Part
I, "Market Mechanisms," and Part
II, "Economic Policy." That government plays vital roles in
facilitating markets was clearly recognized by Smith, as was the need to
consider the entire complex of pertinent government policies when analyzing any
economic system. Much of the theoretical work that followed elaborated on
Smith's work and continued his attack on government constraints on economic
markets, especially with respect to international trade. See, Ricardo,
"Principles of Political Economy," and Wolf, "Why
Globalization Works," Part
I, "Globalization of Market Systems." and Part
II, "Criticism of Market System Globalization."
|
The
capitalist system is characterized by "indirect governance through
regulated competition" both in economic and political markets. |
|
It is an economically, politically and legally empowered civil society working through the political markets and the courts that maintain limits on political excess.
"Only a political authority can correct these market frameworks, and this in itself should warn us that externalities will never be eliminated. Thus a market economy should be presumed to contain distortions that range from small to large, and even 'extra-large.'" |
The political and economic systems are interdependent,
with each influencing the other. Competitive economic markets provide economic
discipline and accountability through the trading process, and competitive political markets provide
political discipline and accountability through the election process.
Thus, the maintenance of competitive capitalist markets
that meet the broad economic needs of the people and the nation depends on the
political markets functioning properly to assure that both political and
economic markets work for the
people instead of just for the politically influential and economically
powerful. |
Capitalism is as much a political phenomenon as an economic one. It involves - and requires - not just Smith's "invisible hand" in economic markets, but the "visible hands" of political actors in political markets. |
Capitalism must be viewed as part of a system
where economic markets are embedded in institutions designed and governed by
political authority. Free markets alone do not constitute capitalism. Capitalism is as much a political phenomenon as an
economic one. It involves - and requires - not just Smith's
"invisible hand" in economic markets, but the "visible
hands" of political actors in political markets. In
democracies, political markets include elections, legislatures, and the
activities of civil society and economic interests. "Visible hand"
impacts of human agency also flow from government and private agencies and institutions that
have economic authority. |
The huge concentrations of industrial power were ironically used by socialists and communists as a reason for establishing "a centrally planned, coercive state that would monopolize power even more" than either feudalism or the 19th century industrial giants. |
"Smith's conception of atomistic capitalism, where
firms had little or no economic power," was already an inadequate framework for
analyzing capitalist systems as they had developed by the last part of the 19th
century. By that time, capitalist markets were dominated by vast industrial giants.
Democracies were few in number at that time and governments had not launched any
efforts to "embed markets in regulatory frameworks" to protect labor
or other interests. |
Competition cannot be the only regulatory agency.
The need for a broader focus than mathematical economists can provide is obvious. |
Other critics, most prominently Milton Friedman, have also provided alternatives to the narrow focus of the modern economists, but Friedman's focus, too, has been too narrow. Scott criticizes Friedman for concentrating on the abuse of political power and ignoring the potential for abuse of economic power. (See, three articles beginning with Friedman & Schwartz, "A Monetary History of the U.S.(1867-1960)," Part I, "Greenbacks and Gold (1867-1921)") Competition may be a powerful disciplinary force in the economic markets, but its impact on market participants may vary greatly with size, geographical position, economic status and other factors. The interests of those with "meager resources, little education or human capital, and/or no financial capital with which to take advantage of market opportunities," will not be adequately protected by unfettered markets. Competition cannot be the only regulatory agency.
The need for a broader focus than mathematical
economists can provide is obvious. Economic influence can undermine political functions
just as political influence can undermine economic functions, Scott points out.
"Economic power can be a force for the subversion of equality among
persons, and thus a force for the subversion of freedom and democracy." |
Neo-classical theory has proven inadequate as a basis for development policy. "It is concerned with the operation of markets, not with how the markets develop." |
The five decades of failure of development economics
since WW-II proves the inadequacy of neo-classical theory as a basis for
development policy. "It is concerned with the operation of markets, not
with how the markets develop," Scott points out. |
Trajectories of economic development:
& |
The differing trajectories of economic development in Latin America
as compared with North America, and in the southern regions of the U.S.
and Italy as compared with their
northern regions, are covered in some detail by Scott. The author emphasizes the
differences in governance, social customs, political and private sector
institutions - the stuff of political economy. |
Path dependency phenomena played a major role in the underdeveloped regions as privileged elites fought the development of the political and private governance structures required for capitalist development. |
British colonists in Jamaica and the southern colonies of North
America followed much the same development trajectory as the Spanish and Portuguese
colonists in Latin America. These underdeveloped regions all responded to
similar geographic
comparative advantages. The common denominator was
the presence of "rich factor endowments that could be exploited by forced
labor." The operative "cultural factors" were
clearly not ethnic.
Political and ethnic culture factors come more into play in Argentina and French
Canada, where centralized political regimes reinforced elite privileges and
inhibited economic development. |
The granting of title to property is clearly not enough to mobilize capital in the absence of the appropriate legal framework to enforce both property and creditor rights in a timely and cost-effective manner.
Remedies for the distorted factor markets and paucity of public goods must come through the "visible hand" of political policy. |
Clientelism, corrupt extra judicial relationships, and inadequate public goods and services such as infrastructure, education, legal protections for people and property, inadequate access to domestic financing and lack of technological development continue to plague most Latin American nations. Centralized political systems combine with impotent and corrupt local governance to retard development.
Hernando de Soto in "The
Mystery of Capital," provides an incomplete analysis of the credit
problem, Scott points out. The problem is not a shortage of capital, but the
absence of the appropriate governing institutions of capitalism. The granting of title to property is clearly not enough to mobilize
capital in the absence of the appropriate legal framework to enforce both
property and creditor rights in a timely and cost-effective manner. Bankruptcy
laws and banking systems, and broad social acceptance of the pertinent legal
processes - again, the stuff of political economy - are also essential. |
Unlike product markets, factor markets for land, labor, finance and the natural resources of the commons cannot evolve naturally. They require the "visible hand of human agency," the author points out. |
|
Capitalism is certainly more than a system for trading. It is the production paradigm that "is most susceptible to gross abuses of power," and is most subject to the influence of human agency within the capitalist system. If political actors do not develop and maintain property rights, contract rights, rule of law systems and the whole panoply of supporting and regulatory institutions, modern capitalism cannot exist. |
Human agency -
human political choices - play a major role in the development of the pertinent
institutions, Scott emphasizes. The focus on the "trading paradigm" misses the aspect of
capitalism which bears most directly on the "productive paradigm"
involving the marshalling of resources for profitable development.
As focus on the production paradigm demonstrates, capitalism is certainly more than a system for trading. It is the production paradigm that "is most susceptible to gross abuses of power," and is most subject to the influence of human agency within the capitalist system. If political actors do not develop and maintain property rights, contract rights, rule of law systems and the whole panoply of supporting and regulatory institutions, modern capitalism and its factor markets cannot exist.
The essential elements of the capitalist economy thus include not just the product markets but also the factor markets and the supporting institutions and the political activities that develop and govern them. Politics includes political and societal institutions that are generally studied in the field of political science and remain outside the purview of economists. However, the contests for political influence have a direct impact on economic developments, and economic influence directly influences political developments.
|
Market participants act in the relatively free economic markets within the bounds of laws and rules that establish acceptable behavior.
Any economic system can have markets to trade products, but the lending of capital, the sale of land, and the contracting of labor require a particular social and legal system that permits and enforces freely negotiated contracts involving the factors of production.
The market system described by Friedman essentially describes informal gray or black market trade or the roadside fruit stand, not capitalism. |
Scott explains capitalism as a three level system
of (1) economic markets, (2) private and public institutions, and (3) political authority
accountable in political markets. It is an indirect system of governance, since
market participants act in the relatively free economic markets within the
bounds of laws and rules that establish acceptable behavior. Informal
customs among market participants are of course also very important. Any economic system can have markets to trade
products, but the lending of capital, the sale of land, and the contracting of
labor require a particular social and legal system that permits and enforces
freely negotiated contracts involving the factors of production.
Friedman's view, the author points out, is that most market
constraints should be by the customs developed over time by market participants.
Markets should be impersonal, apolitical, and unbiased, and government should
play as minimal a role as possible. However, even Friedman accepts that
government's role has to include doing what "the market cannot do for
itself, namely to determine, arbitrate and enforce the rules of the game." But
Scott asserts that the market system described by Friedman essentially describes informal gray or black
market trade or the roadside fruit stand, not capitalism. It would be neither as
efficient nor transparent as appropriately governed capitalist markets. |
The laws "are always created by political actors and therefore, to some extent, always contain a political agenda or tilt within them." |
The assertion that market capitalism "separates
economic activities from political views" is a practical impossibility,
the author points out in a further criticism of Milton Friedman. Political biases are
inherent realities in these as in all political actions. The laws "are
always created by political actors and therefore, to some extent, always contain
a political agenda or tilt within them." Economic analysis must be broad
enough to encompass this political fact of life. |
Laws and regulations designed to facilitate markets contrast with those designed to burden markets or constrain them in favor of political purposes and/or the politically influential.
In addition to the market price mechanism, capitalism requires an elaborate institutional framework including "the administrative apparatus through which the visible hand of government translates estimated societal costs and benefits into various rights, taxes, and subsidies in order to approximate true social costs for each particular society." |
Laws and regulations designed to facilitate markets
contrast with those designed to burden markets or constrain them in favor of
political purposes and/or the
politically influential. As an example of a rule that facilitates a market,
Scott refers to the credit card requirement that issuers assume
responsibility for most charges on lost or stolen cards. The issuers
can spread these costs widely and most effectively act to minimize them. This
rule
increases cardholder confidence in the use of the cards. (Title registration
laws are another widely appreciated example.)
|
Democratic governments thus have an unavoidable responsibility to protect the citizenry from the abuse of economic power. They must also provide a wide range of "public goods." The study of economics and the analysis of economic markets thus must include both the political and economic spheres and all their interactions. |
As in professional sports, the institutional context shapes
but does not control competitive behavior. In the formative years, the rules of
a sport draw upon "custom,
consensus and un-coerced conformity," evolving over time. However, modern professional games are governed by formal rule-making
bodies. Modern capitalist markets are governed according to sometimes narrow
majorities in legislatures and courts. For both professional sports and
capitalism, formal rule-making bodies provide
"indirect governance" that shapes the competitive playing fields but does not - or should not - determine competitive outcomes.
Scott defines "laissez faire" policy as
"self-regulatory markets with a weak state" concerned mainly with
promoting producer interests. The system he characterizes as "laissez
faire" involves "institutional arrangements [that] already embody a
strategy, no matter how implicit or shortsighted that strategy might be." ( Used thus as a pejorative, the phrase obfuscates
rather than illuminates.) |
Even those like Madison who favored federal chartering authority ultimately abandoned it as inconsistent with the desired limits to federal power. |
The fear of centralized power of the founding fathers and
the ratifying public was the cause of the weakness of federal economic
authority. This fear guided their actions both before and after
the ratification of the Constitution. Scott points out that these views
are evident in how Thomas Jefferson shaped the Northwest Ordinance just before
the Constitutional Convention, and why
Pres. Madison vetoed a bill that would have permitted federal funding of
infrastructure, a task he thought Constitutionally left to the states.
|
Competition between states striving to attract economic resources led to the spread of laws favoring producers and commercial interests. No one was "looking out for the public interest."
Courts responded by viewing corporate charters under state corporation laws as simply "a convenient device for conducting business" rather than as a privilege subject to state purposes. Corporations had to comply with the laws of the land, including general regulatory provisions, but retained the same rights as individuals with respect to corporate purposes. |
State legislatures responded to their
economic authority as might be expected - with widespread instances
of corruption in favor of the politically influential. The public
response was to amend state constitutions to limit the discretionary economic policy authority
of state legislatures.
Yet again, the power of private parties was favored over that of the state. Courts responded by viewing corporate charters under state corporation laws as simply "a convenient device for conducting business" rather than as a privilege subject to state purposes. Corporations had to comply with the laws of the land, including general regulatory provisions, but retained the same rights as individuals with respect to corporate purposes. The author goes at some length into examples of abuse of private powers, corrupt private practices and massive miscalculation.
Scott emphasizes the railroads as the
quintessential example of industrialization and economic power in this
period. Textile firms and railroads led the way in the
formation of modern, large-scale industrial organization. Their methods
were adopted in the coal, iron and steel sectors. However, private competition
led to periods of over-expansion followed inevitably by periods of
economic contraction and enhanced creative destruction. |
Scott refers to the 19th century Robber Barons as "oligarchs," and uses the same term for the powerful financial sector leaders in the U.S. since 1980.
The courts were powerful actors, interpreting legal doctrine in favor of economic growth and thus in favor of producer and commercial interests.
Private economic actors were able to pursue their private economic interests "largely unaccountable to any public regulatory authority state or federal." |
The vast growth of power and political as well as economic influence
of the 19th century industrial giants provides prominent examples of how
unfettered market participants can destroy freedom in political as well as
economic markets. Economic power can be, and has been, abused just like
political power. The author emphasizes that markets can be shaped to work for the few rather than for the
many. This has in fact been common in oligopolist nations from Russia and
Central Asia to Latin America. (NOTE that these states all have highly
centralized political systems such as the Constitution was designed to
prevent.)
|
The 1887 Interstate Commerce Commission Act and the 1890 Sherman Antitrust Act signaled the entry of the federal government as a significant regulatory power.
Initiative and referendum reforms at the state level, direct election of senators, and the 1913 Federal Reserve Act laid some groundwork for increased political opposition to the excesses of consolidated producer and commercial interests. |
Opposition supporting a political policy response
developed towards
the end of the 19th century. The 1887 Interstate Commerce Commission Act
and the 1890 Sherman Antitrust Act signaled the entry of the federal
government as a significant regulatory power. There were state
regulatory efforts, also, but all these efforts were essentially beaten
back by industry political influence and their success in legal
proceedings.
|
The Supreme Court interpreted federal regulatory initiatives as efforts to facilitate market disciplinary mechanisms rather than to displace them with administered alternatives. |
Business support shifted in favor of federal
regulation in response to the proliferation of a bewildering variety
of state regulations. A series of federal reforms were passed in the
first two decades of the 20th century. The Interstate Commerce
Commission and the courts, however, continued to interpret these laws to
favor market mechanisms, producer and commercial interests and economic growth. The Supreme
Court, in particular, interpreted most federal regulatory initiatives as
efforts to facilitate market disciplinary mechanisms rather than to
displace them with administered alternatives. & |
The Supreme Court shifted from recognizing Constitutional limits on the economic powers of Congress to accepting Congress as the authorized problem solver for the nation without Constitutional limits, at least in the economic sphere.
"The Framers and then the courts prioritized individual freedom over state power," and corporation law evolved to extend such freedoms to corporations. |
The change in judicial philosophy during the New Deal
is emphasized by Scott. In short, with its New Deal appointments,
the Supreme Court shifted from recognizing Constitutional limits on the
economic powers of Congress to accepting Congress as the authorized problem
solver for the nation without Constitutional limits, at least in the economic
sphere. In academic circles, the shift is described as being from
"Classical Legal Thought" that recognizes Constitutional constraints
on the economic powers of Congress to "Legal Realism."
|
The removal of market interest rates by Fed Chairman Greenspan, the reduction of mortgage lending standards and the "too-big-to-fail" credit subsidies that transformed credit market vigilantes into credit market enablers, are acknowledged by ScottScott, as is the noxious impacts of the government's poorly conceived and disastrously implemented affordable housing policies. |
The noxious impacts of the removal of market interest rates by Fed Chairman Greenspan, the reduction of mortgage lending standards and the "too-big-to-fail" credit subsidies that transformed credit market vigilantes into credit market enablers, are acknowledged by Scott. He also notes the noxious impacts of the government's poorly conceived and disastrously implemented affordable housing policies.
Where Scott is indubitably 100% correct is that any analysis and understanding of the Credit Crunch must involve the political, institutional and societal environment. (See, Understanding the Credit Crunch.) Narrowly focused economic analysis is inherently incompetent, and mathematical analysis an obvious farce. Only analysis into the broad realms of political economy can suffice.
|
Social democratic system in Europe, by contrast, include social insurance for sickness, accidents, retirement and unemployment, collective bargaining rights and methods to increase the share of national income for labor. They also include the high levels of taxation required to finance the system. |
In Europe, government policy heavily influenced the course of economic development. Social democratic systems there have policies that protect "both labor and consumers from the full effects of lightly regulated competition, and notably in the markets for capital and labor." They include social insurance for sickness, accidents, retirement and unemployment, collective bargaining rights and methods to increase the share of national income for labor. They also include the high levels of taxation required to finance the system.
|
Democratic governments thus have an unavoidable responsibility to protect the citizenry from the abuse of economic power. They must also provide a wide range of "public goods." |
Power inequality in both political and economic markets, how inequality grows to threatening levels, and
the institutional mechanisms that might reduce and limit it, are vital issues
stressed by Scott. He emphasizes that
market failure can happen in both domains, but only the "visible hand"
of political action can remedy market failure in either domain. Indeed, analysis
of the political domain in general and the development and operations of
democracy are of as much a concern of this book as analysis of the economic
domain and the development and operations of capitalism. |
The growth of the entitlement welfare state must be a major factor in evaluation of the nation's economic prospects in the 21st century. |
|
The power relationships in capitalist systems are
emphasized by Scott. He focuses on the scope and interplay of the linkages
between economic and political power. |
|
Capitalism cannot be understood without the political inputs of "human agency." There is and always has been a "visible hand" involved in shaping free market capitalism through political processes.
Capitalist free markets are embedded in institutions of public administration and government.
It is the state that grants the power to enter, compete and exit from markets, and restrains participants from abuse of such power. Market participants are compelled to follow the rules. |
Economic analysis must cover "the basic institutional foundations, including physical and social infrastructure as well as the individuals and organizations operating them." Numerous alphabet soup institutions play governing and administrative roles in the U.S. The author mentions transportation and communications infrastructure as well as educational, public health and legal systems. These institutions define acceptable market behavior. They are agents of the state.
Above them all are the political institutions that govern political markets. In democracies, they include reasonably fair elections and the influence of a politically, legally and economically empowered civil society. "Laws do not make themselves or enforce themselves. Unless there is demand for enforcement, it will not normally happen." Capitalism cannot be understood without the political inputs of "human agency." There is and always has been a "visible hand" involved in shaping free market capitalism through political processes.
Indeed, a political authority is an essential ingredient for
capitalism. The political authority must have "legitimacy to govern the
economic system, the political power to reshape and/or modernize its
institutions, and the coercive power to see that its decisions are
implemented." Capitalism implies economic freedom, but "all such
freedoms are conditional on obedience to the rules embedded in the system."
|
Aside from nations suffering from the oil or other natural resources curse, it is from a prosperous market economy that governments draw their revenues and derive their power - political, economic, diplomatic and military.
Human political agency was involved "in the design of economic institutions to pursue societal objectives, actively directing the markets towards their desired equilibria." |
The state, in turn, has a powerful interest in the efficient
functioning of its markets. Aside from nations suffering from the oil or other
natural resources curse, it is from a prosperous market economy that governments
draw their revenues and derive their power - political, economic, diplomatic and military.
Historically, during times of military threat, free market nations like Great
Britain and the Netherlands actively mobilized their economic resources for use
in their conflicts. Even mercantilist policies could be justified as a means of
mobilizing economic power for state purposes.
However, equilibrium alone is not enough. Equilibrium may be at a very low point due to distortions or inefficiencies affecting the market. Scott mentions the Great Depression and also the Credit Crunch with the prior expansion of the housing and mortgage debt bubbles. During the Credit Crunch, the markets struggled to maintain and regain equilibrium in supply and demand against major distorting influences. (See, "Moral Hazard and Conflicts of Interest in the Credit Crunch.")
|
Capitalism thus must be analyzed as a mix of sociology,
administration, politics, economics and law. |
|
"The essential institutions of capitalism cannot develop along with the needs of society absent the informed and capable input of human agents, such as those empowered through a government."
Economic analysts thus have no choice but to cover the mix of political influences when analyzing market conditions. Political authorities must be held accountable for policies that adversely impact the markets. |
Capitalism must be viewed as including the "political level" where human agency impacts markets. Economic development is dependent on responsible governance as much as on free domestic and international markets.
The political role may appear static in the short run. As the system
operates according to its existing rules and regulations, government is involved only in an
administrative capacity. However, government is not just a "given"
factor. As time passes, changing conditions in the
markets and changing societal objectives require adjustments to the laws and
regulations that only political authority can provide. Thus, political markets
are just as dynamic and vital as economic markets in understanding capitalism.
Indeed, it is the political institutional framework that creates the
capitalist markets, Scott emphasizes. Capitalist markets can facilitate the
building of individual wealth and the economic power of the nation. Without
their institutional framework and political governance, however, markets can be nothing
more than town marketplaces or Middle East bazaars that facilitate little more
than subsistence living. |
With oligarchy, there can be limited monarchy, council governance with the power of the purse, rule of law, incentives to facilitate commerce, and other factors of a capitalist system
The "visible hand" within governmental and private institutions was vital in the continuous modernization of the regulatory framework. |
It is thus oligarchy that is most compatible with capitalist
development, as proven by about 1000 years of experience in Venice prior to
1800. With oligarchy, there can be limited monarchy, council governance with the
power of the purse, rule of law, incentives to facilitate commerce, and other
factors of a capitalist system. The view that it was inevitable is both
simplistic and untenable. It "required institutional innovation that would
disrupt the status quo and take power from vested interests." As capitalism
builds and spreads wealth, the shift from oligarchy is also neither automatic
nor inevitable. Strong broader political accountability came late in this
process. Democracy may be favored by the spread of wealth, but it is the work of
the "visible hand" of political actors in legislative bodies. These
"are the political choices of political economy." |
Cities could provide the ingredients for the generation of wealth, but capitalism is what actually generated it.
Much of this competition between political entities was unique to Europe. |
Early forms of European capitalism developed in city states
like Venice, Florence and Genoa on Mediterranean trade routes or on river trade
routes in central Europe far enough away from Spain or France, the dominant
powers of that time, to enjoy some temporary period of autonomy. Capitalist
elements that developed at that time included factor markets for manufactures, land
and labor, double entry bookkeeping, bills of exchange, formal legal systems for
disputes resolution, and various political authorities. Insurance for commercial
ventures was developed in Genoa in the 14th century. Various forms of banking
and the enforcement of contracts and property rights were also features of these
early capitalist systems. |
The development of the Atlantic trade routes radically changed
this picture. Long trade routes required capital and the spreading of risk.
European inheritance laws permitted the concentration of family wealth, and the
development of the joint stock company in the 16th century overcame the
limitations of partnership organization. Capital markets based on bank credit
and state credit were developed. Interest rates for prime credit risks were
already in sharp decline before this period, so credit availability played a
major role in capitalist development.
|
|
"Stable political governance providing market frameworks as modified by political authorities which were accountable to a rule of law" was a European political economy phenomenon.
Wars, revolutions and executions of sovereigns were part of the process. It took centuries, but the Reformation loosened the suffocating grip of the Church. The Enlightenment freed reason from ideological fetters.
|
European states were responsible for providing market frameworks based upon a rule of law in return for taxes and loyalty. "Stable political governance providing market frameworks as modified by political authorities which were accountable to a rule of law" was a European political economy phenomenon.
Change in different
places in different times undermined rigid feudal arrangements. However, change
came through political decisions rather than impersonal market forces. These
were not smooth impersonal processes of economic growth. Wars, revolutions and
executions of sovereigns were part of the process. It took centuries, but the
Reformation loosened the suffocating grip of the Church. The Enlightenment freed
reason from ideological fetters. The rise of the nation state provided a single
source for law and political authority. Clergy and nobility were disenfranchised
in different ways and times in different nations. This opened the way for a
broadening of political participation by the public and the establishment of
modern professional administrative departments. Scott reviews the many different
paths that this process followed in different nations and regions. |
The new ingredient was the acceptance of the notion that there should be a return on investment - a return on capital as well as labor - something religious authorities had frowned upon.
Rule of law and central banks in Venice, Netherlands and England provided credibility and a significant financial advantage for those states. Borrowing costs were about 1/3 that of the absolute monarchies in France and Spain.
It is governance that is the key to capitalist development, and as it turns out, capitalism is key to political modernization. |
The process was driven by competition between political entities
and the realization that economic strength was the basis of military strength
and the major source of funds for the ruling elites. The new ingredient was the
acceptance of the notion that there should be a return on investment - a return
on capital as well as labor - something religious authorities had frowned
upon.
Spain suffered the curse of natural resource wealth. It failed to develop politically or commercially, and declined with the decline of its American mines. Inflation and three bankruptcies in the 16th century undermined its great power status. Portugal similarly failed to modernize.
Outside Europe, wealthy, powerful empires stagnated and declined.
"It was in the East that rulers were truly rich and their subjects
miserably poor." Scott reviews the suffocating governance characteristics
of India, Turkey, China, Japan, that persisted for centuries in the absence of
political competition from external threats. Again, it is governance that is the
key to capitalist development, and as it turns out, capitalism is key to
political modernization. |
Disruptions of political arrangements due to changing conditions must be dealt with by the "visible hand" of political actors in competitive political markets and legislative markets. Political action is also required to facilitate economic development through appropriate infrastructure and institutional development.
Success required that those with political power relinquish some of it for the benefit of private actors who would put mostly private capital at risk and pay taxes for the privilege of trying and succeeding." |
Capitalism involves a constant process of change typically involving urbanization, industrialization, the development of services and financial sectors, the development of an educated civil society, and accelerated technological change. The resulting disruptions of political arrangements must be dealt with by the "visible hand" of political actors in competitive political markets and legislative markets. Political action is also required to facilitate economic development through appropriate infrastructure and institutional development.
Both government and private efforts can involve massive and costly mistakes. "But historically speaking, political actors have been key; success required that those with political power relinquish some of it for the benefit of private actors who would put mostly private capital at risk and pay taxes for the privilege of trying and succeeding."
|
The roots of capitalism in the North American colonies can be
traced to just before 1630 when Plymouth colonists reacted to the failures
of communal farming by privatizing the land. This created private property
wealth, with "stunning" agricultural success. |
|
The egalitarian pattern of development is viewed by the author as a key element in this success.
Market liberalization by itself could not overcome privileged elite obstruction of economic and political development in the south. Thus, the southern states failed to prosper despite favorable factor endowments until reform was forced by federal government political and legal intervention.
In the south of Italy and in many Latin American states, market forces alone still cannot produce economic development. The elements of political economy are essential for understanding these developments. |
With limited factor endowments, the northern colonies offered no easy route to great wealth. Thus, state resources were dependent on the development
of a prosperous populace. Governance was thus naturally
directed towards the facilitation of the people's commerce. Investments in human
resources and effective institutions ultimately proved more valuable than the gold
and silver mines and the great plantations worked by forced labor.
Market liberalization by itself could not overcome the privileged elites
who obstructed economic and political development in the south. Thus, the
southern states failed to prosper despite favorable factor endowments until
reform was forced by federal government political and legal intervention.
Cultural change in the north was a vital factor in ending segregation and
providing political support for federal government civil rights enforcement in
the south. In the south of Italy and in many Latin American states, market
forces alone still cannot produce economic development. The elements of
political economy are essential for understanding the economic failures. |
The political markets of pseudo-democracy in Jamaica were more like the authoritarianism of feudalism around them than they were like the British model back home or indeed in North America. If there is a chance for a few to seize power to exploit the many, it is an almost irresistible temptation." |
French North America concentrated on exploiting
the fur trade along the great waterways extending from the St. Lawrence to the
Mississippi river. The author points out that property was communal and so no capitalist wealth developed
even in the French settlements along the St. Lawrence. Governance was feudal and
monarchic in the settlements and tribal elsewhere amongst the Indian tribes.
|
Large initial land grants were made in both Argentina and Pennsylvania. All land was kept in centralized control in Argentina and doled out to favored elites. In Pennsylvania, the offer of egalitarian opportunities resulted in rapid economic development. |
Patron-client relationships played major roles in hindering
economic development in Italian and U.S. southern regions. There were a variety
of political weaknesses. Only the mobilization of political power can overcome entrenched
privileged elites. Notoriously, for southern Italy, the picture includes exploitative patron-client
social systems like the Mafia. The author provides some historic perspective.
In the southern states of the U.S., the explanation for an economic trajectory that differs from that in the northern states both before and after the Civil War, and the failure of convergence until 1940, is to be found in the factors of political economy - social, institutional and political - rather than in economic factors alone. After the Civil War, plantation landholdings remained in the hands of white elites. The system of sharecropping functioned in a manner similar to the patron-client systems in southern Italy. Sharecroppers were economically dependent on the owners of the lands they worked because of the limited scope for black labor mobility until WW-I. Antebellum values tilted the economic markets in ways that favored the elites and prevented the economic convergence that could be expected under economic theory. Scott goes into considerable detail on this point.
The overall theory favored by the author again depends on factor endowment - an agricultural version of the "natural resources curse."
Public goods such as law enforcement, education and infrastructure were typical casualties of all of these systems. The exceptions included Argentina, Chile, Uruguay and southern Brazil, where the factor endowments were similar to those in the northern colonies. However, these regions still wound up with vastly unequal land holdings and wealth and the political and social institutions typical of such conditions. Governance was centralized from the beginning so land holdings and wealth were concentrated in elite hands in the Iberian style.
Large initial land grants were made in both Argentina and
Pennsylvania. All land was kept in centralized control in Argentina and doled
out to favored elites. In Pennsylvania, the offer of egalitarian opportunities
resulted in rapid economic development. |
& |
The "visible hand" of political decisions
was prominently involved in the facilitation of capitalism in North
America. Scott reviews the political and economic development of the U.S. Local government dependent on local commerce and the value of local
real estate for its revenues remained the focus of political and economic
governance in the U.S. until the Great Depression. & |
The Northwest Ordinance just before the Constitutional Convention extended the preference for small landholdings into the frontier regions. It abolished primogeniture and entails and provided land surveys and boundary markers that facilitated private property rights in fee simple. It reserved lands to support public education.
|
The Constitution displays the "visible hand" of political
decisions affecting the economy in many ways. It established judicial
supremacy and state power in the economic realm over intrastate commerce. The
courts became instruments of economic development by interpreting the laws to favor producers over consumers. "Markets still
reached equilibrium, but playing fields were tilted toward producers almost from
independence ." |
|
The peculiar character of the U.S. economy resides in Constitutional
constraints on the exercise of political power and the existence
of 50 semi-autonomous states each constrained by the need to compete with each
other for economic resources. The federal government, with its persistent
efforts to expand its Commerce Clause powers, can override these constraints on
economic governance, but it remains subject to competition from sovereign nations in
the global markets. Global markets can be seen forcing political leadership even
in more centralized nations to conform (kicking and screaming all the way) to
economic market disciplines. & |
In a globalized world, the failure to develop is attributable
not to economic factors but to factors of political economy, to dysfunctional
institutions and failure to provide physical security for persons and their
property, Scott continuously emphasizes. Governments that lack the will or
capacity to reform pertinent institutions are at the heart of developmental
failure. Market forces cannot overcome entrenched institutional barriers (unless
economic failure reaches a point where the existing governance structures are
swept away). & |
||
"Institutional innovations were initiated through the ad hoc decisions of legislatures, regulators, and courts of a governance system that had little capacity to coordinate among the various levels and subsystems of government. Indeed, competition among states to attract business investment undermined standards of public accountability for private actors." |
Scott sums up:
This all changed in 1936 when Franklin D. Roosevelt appointed two new
Supreme Court justices who were more accepting of legislative powers, especially
at the federal level. Congress would thereafter be the "deciding voice in
the U.S. capitalist framework." |
|
Scott, "Capitalism: Origins and Evolution as a System of Governance," addresses a variety of modern political economy issues. See, Part II, "Oligarchs and Stakeholders and other Issues of Political Economy." These issues include:
As might be expected, the author and FUTURECASTS have some agreements and some disagreements on these issues. FUTURECASTS readers are encouraged to add their input. E-mail comments to blat1@futurecasts.com. |
Please return to our Homepage and e-mail your name and comments.